RAJASTHAN CYLINDERS AND CONTAINERS LIMITED Vs U.O.I AND ANR
Bench: HON'BLE MR. JUSTICE A.K. SIKRI, HON'BLE MR. JUSTICE ASHOK BHUSHAN
Judgment by: HON'BLE MR. JUSTICE A.K. SIKRI
Case number: C.A. No.-003546-003546 / 2014
Diary number: 3644 / 2014
Advocates: SARLA CHANDRA Vs
Page 1
Page 2
Page 3
Page 4
Page 5
Page 6
Page 7
Page 8
Page 9
Page 10
Page 11
Page 12
Page 13
Page 14
Page 15
Page 16
Page 17
Page 18
Page 19
Page 20
Page 21
Page 22
Page 23
Page 24
Page 25
Page 26
Page 27
Page 28
Page 29
Page 30
Page 31
Page 32
Page 33
Page 34
Page 35
Page 36
Page 37
Page 38
Page 39
Page 40
Page 41
Page 42
Page 43
Page 44
Page 45
Page 46
Page 47
Page 48
Page 49
Page 50
Page 51
Page 52
Page 53
Page 54
Page 55
Page 56
Page 57
Page 58
Page 59
Page 60
Page 61
Page 62
Page 63
Page 64
Page 65
Page 66
Page 67
Page 68
Page 69
Page 70
Page 71
Page 72
Page 73
Page 74
Page 75
Page 76
Page 77
Page 78
Page 79
Page 80
Page 81
Page 82
Page 83
Page 84
Page 85
Page 86
Page 87
Page 88
1
REPORTABLE
IN THE SUPREME COURT OF INDIA
CIVIL APPELLATE JURISDICTION
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 3546 OF 2014
RAJASTHAN CYLINDERS AND CONTAINERS LIMITED
.....APPELLANT(S)
VERSUS
UNION OF INDIA AND ANOTHER .....RESPONDENT(S)
W I T H
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 4280 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 4346 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 4649 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 4342 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 4879 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 4868 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6033 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 5771 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 5772 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 5035 OF 2014
2
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 5773 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 5649 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 5650 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 5651 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 4972 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6661 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 7102 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6868 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 7214 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6025 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6365 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NOS. 5993-5994 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 5774 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 5775 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 5776 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NOS. 5832-5833 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 5777 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 5778 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6317 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 8953 OF 2014
3
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6372 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6373 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6366 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6367 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6374 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6368 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6364 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6369 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 6370 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 10579 OF 2014
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 1724 OF 2015
CIVIL APPEAL NOS. 5277-5278 OF 2016
CIVIL APPEAL NOS. 5281-5315 OF 2016
AND
CIVIL APPEAL NO. 7359 OF 2016
J U D G M E N T
A.K. SIKRI, J.
4
All these appeals are filed against the orders dated 20 th December,
2013 passed by the Competition Appellate Tribunal (hereinafter referred to
as ‘COMPAT’). The COMPAT by the said judgment has upheld the findings
of the Competition Commission of India (for short, ‘CCI’) that the
appellants/suppliers of Liquefied Petroleum Gas (LPG) Cylinders to the
Indian Oil Corporation Ltd. (for short, ‘IOCL’) had indulged in cartilisation,
thereby influencing and rigging the prices, thus, violating the provisions of
Section 3(3)(d) of the Competition Act, 2002 (for short, the ‘Act’). The CCI,
as a result, imposed severe penalties in the form of fines under Section 27
of the Act. While maintaining the order of the CCI insofar as it found the
appellants guilty of contravention of Section 3(3)(d) and also under Section
3(3)(a) of the Act, the COMPAT has reduced the amount of penalty. These
suppliers have filed the instant appeals on the ground that there was no
cartilisation and they have not contravened the provisions of the Act. On
the other hand, CCI has also come up in appeal challenging latter part of
the order whereby penalties inflicted on the suppliers stand reduced. For
the sake of convenience these suppliers will be referred to as the
appellants hereinafter.
2) We may point out at the outset that all these appellants are manufacturing
5
gas cylinders of a particular specification having capacity of 14.2 kg which
are needed for use by the three oil companies in India, namely, IOCL,
Bharat Petroleum Corporation Ltd. (BPCL) and Hindustan Petroleum
Corporation Ltd. (HPCL) [all public sector companies]. It is also a matter
of record that apart from the aforesaid three companies there are no other
buyers for these cylinders manufactured by the appellants. Insofar as
IOCL is concerned, it is a leading market player in LPG as its market share
is 48%. Thus, in case a particular manufacturer is not able to supply its
cylinders to the aforesaid three companies, there is no other market for
these cylinders and it may force that company to exit from its operations.
We may also point out at this stage itself that inquiry was started against
47 companies. The CCI exonerated two companies and found that 45
companies had entered into an arrangement/agreement insofar as
statements of bids pursuant to tenders issued by IOCL are concerned.
Out of these 45 companies one did not challenge the orders before the
COMPAT and other 44 had filed appeals which have been decided by the
COMPAT.
3) The manner in which the inquiry was undertaken by the CCI, culminating
into the finding of guilt and imposition of penalty, is succintly and sequally
recorded by the COMPAT in its impugned order. As there is no dispute
6
about the said factual narration, it would be convenient to borrow the said
discussion as recorded by the COMPAT.
4) The suo-motu proceedings were started by the CCI on the basis of the
information received by it in Case No. 10 of 2010 titled M/s. Pankaj Gas
Cylinders Ltd. Vs. Indian Oil Corporation Ltd. in that case a complaint was
made by M/s. Pankaj Gas Cylinders before the CCI complaining about
unfair conditions in the tender floated by IOCL for the supply of 105 lakh
14.2 Kg. capacity LPG Cylinders with SC valves in the year 2010-11, the
tender No. being LPG-O/M/PT-03/09-10. While considering the Director
General’s investigation report in Case No. 10 of 2010, the CCI in
pursuance of its duties under Section 18 felt that investigation was
necessary in the case of all bidders who were the suppliers of 14.2 kg.
LPG cylinders in that tender. In the investigation report in the said case,
the Director General had noted that out of 63 bidders who participated in
the tender, 50 bidders were qualified for opening of price bids, while 12
bidders were qualified as new vendors who were not required to submit
price bids and one bidder was not qualified for the opening of the price bid.
The technical bid of the subject tender was opened on 3.3.2010 and the
price bids of 50 qualified bidders were opened on 23.3.2010. According to
the Director General, there was a similar pattern in the bids by all the 50
7
bidders who submitted price bids for various States. The bids of a large
number of parties were exactly identical or near to identical for different
States. The Director General had observed that there were strong
indications of some sort of agreement and understanding amongst the
bidders to manipulate the process of bidding.
5) It was on this basis the CCI directed further investigation in the matter. The
Director General after careful consideration submitted a detailed
investigation report to the CCI. After the CCI considered the freshly
ordered investigation report, it directed that a copy of the report be sent to
the parties seeking their objections. In all, 44 opposite parties submitted
their objections. After giving them the opportunity to be heard, the CCI
passed the order in question.
6) As per the Director General’s report, the process of bidding followed by the
IOCL in the tender was as under :-
i) The bidders would submit their quotations with the bid documents.
ii) The existing bidders, who were existing suppliers, were required to
submit the price bids and technical bids.
iii) The bidders were to quote for supplies in different States of India in
keeping with their installed capacity.
iv) After price bids were opened the bidders were arranged according to
8
the rates in the categories of L-1, L-2 and L-3.
v) The rates for the supplies in different States were approved after
negotiations with L-1 bidder. In case the L-1 bidder could not supply a
required number of cylinders in a particular State, the orders of supplies
went to L-2 and also L-3 bidder or likewise depending upon the
requirement in that State as per fixed formula provided in the bid
documents.
vi) Certain bidders were called new parties. They were required to submit
only technical bids and to supply as per L-1 rates determined after the
negotiations.
vii) One bidder could quote for maximum eight States.
7) The Director General after analyzing the bids came to the conclusion that
there was not only a similarity of pattern in the price bids submitted by the
50 bidders for making supply to the IOCL but the bids of large number of
parties were exactly identical or near to identical in different States. It was
also found that bidders, who belonged to same group, might have
submitted identical rates. It was found that not only there was identical
pricing in case of group concerns but the rates of other entities not
belonging to the group were also found to be identical. The D.G.
painstakingly noted the names of group companies as well as non-group
9
companies. He came to the conclusion that in all 37 entities could not be
said to be belonging to any single group and were independently
controlled. The Director General found it unusual that unrelated firms had
quoted identical rates in different States. The D.G. had analyzed the
bidding pattern for the various parties for all the 25 States. He found that :-
a. The orders were placed on all the 50 successful bidders.
b. The contracts were awarded to the sets of bidders who had quoted
identical rates or near to identical rates in a particular pattern in almost all
the States.
c. There was a common pattern for quotation depending upon the
State. In case of North East the rates were highest, quoted at Rs. 1240
whereas in case of others rates were Rs.1100, Rs.1127 and Rs. 1151.
d. It was found that only for Andaman and Nicobar Islands there was a
single party who had quoted the L-1 rate and got the formal contract. In
other States the contracts were bagged in a group on the basis of identical
or near to identical rates.
e. The similarity of the rates was found even in case of bidders whose
factories and offices were not located at one and the same place in the
States and where they were required to supply was far off from their
factories located in different place.
10
8) The D.G. had found further that though the factors like market conditions
and small number of companies were different, there was a large scale
collusion amongst the bidding parties. He also arrived at a finding to the
effect that the LPG Cylinder Manufacturers had formed an Association in
the name of Indian LPG Cylinders Manufacturers Association and the
members were interacting through this Association and were using the
same as a platform. The date for submitting the bids in the case of the
concerned tender was 3.3.2010 and just two days prior to it, two meetings
were held on 1st and 2nd March, 2010 in Hotel Sahara Star in Mumbai. As
many as 19 parties took part and discussed the tender and, in all
probability, prices were fixed there in collusion with each other. The D.G.
reported that the bidders had agreed for allocation of territories, e.g., the
bidders who quoted the bids for Western India had not generally quoted
for Eastern India and that largely the bidders who quoted the lowest in the
group in Northern India, had not quoted generally in Southern India. The
D.G. also concluded that this behavior created entry barrier and that there
was no accrual of benefits of consumers nor were there any plus factors
like improved production or distribution of the goods or the provision of
services.
9) Ultimately, the D.G. came to the conclusion that there was a cartel like
11
behavior on the part of the bidders and that the factors necessary for the
formation of cartel existed in the instant case. It was also found that there
was certainly a ground to hold concerted action on the part of the bidders.
The D.G. had also noted that the rates quoted for the year 2009-10 and in
years previous to that were also identical in some cases. Thus, he came to
the conclusion that the bids for the year 2010-11 had been manipulated by
50 participating bidders. It was thereafter that the CCI decided to supply
the D.G.’s investigation report to the concerned parties and invite their
objections.
10) A common reply came to be filed as also the individual replies. After
considering the same, the CCI formulated the following issue for
determination:-
“Whether there was any collusive agreement between the participating bidders which directly or indirectly resulted in bid rigging of the tender floated by IOCL in March 2010 for procurement of 14.2 kg. LPG cylinders in contravention of Section 3(3)(d) read with Section 3(1) of the Act?”
11) After considering the oral as well as written submissions, the CCI
answered the issue against the Cylinders Manufacturers and inflicted the
penalties against the present appellants. In its impugned order, while
determining the issue, the CCI, in the first instance, considered the
common replies to the DG’s report filed by as many as 44 opposite
12
parties. It was more or less pleaded that every part of LPG Cylinder is
regulated by the Rules through various Notifications and that the price of
steel constitutes 50% of the total manufacturing cost, so also the price of
the paint, it being an essential raw material. All these factors, including the
taxes which vary from State to State, determine the overall bidding pattern
of the bidders. In para-5.2.3 of the common objection, it was added that
these 44 parties had nominated six agents for depositing their bids on their
behalf and it was a common practice amongst the bidders to direct their
agents to keep close watch on the rates offered by their competitors in
respect of a particular State and this led to the possibility of copying and
matching of the rates quoted in the price bids by many suppliers in a
particular State, who may have appointed common agents. Due to this
reason, cutting and over-writing in the price bids for the tender in question
was noticed by the Director General.
12) It was further pointed out that there were only 62 qualified tenderers
in the whole country, out of whom 12 bidders were classified as new
parties, meaning thereby that they had not supplied Cylinders in last three
years and were not required to bid in the tender. Out of the remaining 50
bidders, there were group companies controlled by single management.
13) The CCI in its detailed order began with considering the scope of
13
constructed bid rigging agreement and cartel. In that the CCI also
considered the 18 famous observations by Lord Denning in case of RRTA
vs. W. H. Smith & Sons Limited regarding the quiet and secret nature of
the agreement between the parties. The CCI then went on to record its
inference holding that there was element of agreement and considered the
following factors in coming to the conclusion. They being:-
1. Market conditions
2. Small number of suppliers
3. Few new entrants
4. Active trade association
5. Repetitive bidding
6. Identical products
7. Few or no substitutes
8. No significant technological changes
9. Meeting of bidders in Mumbai and its agenda.
10. Appointing common agents
11. Identical bids despite varying cost.
14) After consideration of these factors, the CCI came to the conclusion
that it did suggest collusive bidding. Thereafter, the CCI analyzed these
bids for each States and found that all 50 participating bidders had
14
secured the order; that the orders were placed on the said 50 bidders who
had quoted identical rates or near to identical rates in a particular pattern
common to all the parties. CCI also highlighted the facts of absence of
business justification. According to the CCI, the material revealed that the
supplies were effected at the higher cost. After discussing the concepts of
standards of proof and appreciable adverse effect on competition, the CCI
considered the various arguments and repelled those arguments. The CCI
then went on to consider the case law, and in particular the judgment of
this Court in Union of India vs. Hindustan Development Corporation1. It
also took into consideration the arguments raised by the individual parties
and then came to record that cases of M/s. JBM Industries and Punjab
Cylinders, however, were exceptional ones and they could be exonerated.
After this the CCI went on to decide the penalty factor under Section 27 of
the Act.
15) The COMPAT after discussing the findings of the CCI and also taking
note of the arguments of the appellants which were advanced before the
CCI, proceeded with its own discussion. It started with the admitted facts
of the case, and took note of the following such facts:
(A) The tender offers were to be made at Mumbai on 03.03.2010.
Admittedly there were meetings in Hotel Sahara Star, Mumbai on 1st and 1 (1993) 3 SCC 499
15
2nd March, 2010 which were attended by some of the appellants. The D.G.
has held that 19 appellants were represented by various persons in that
meeting. The fact of the meeting having been held was not disputed.
Though some of the appellants stated that they did not attend the
meeting and those who attended the meeting maintained that nothing was
disucssed about the tender, the same was not believed by the COMPAT
and it held that these meetings did relate to the tender offers which were
to be submitted on 03.03.2010. This finding is premised on the basis that
nobody came with the explanation as to what transpired in the meeting or
gave any proof that prices were discussed. Minutes of the meeting were
also not produced.
(B) There is an association of the cylinder manufacturers. All the parties,
except few competing with each other, stated that they were not the
members of that association. A feeble argument was also raised by some
appellants that though they were the members but they were not the active
members thereof. Some of the appellants also argued that they had
abandoned the membership by not contributing the subscription in the later
years. However, the appellants could not deny the position that there was
an association called Indian LPG Cylinder Manufacturers’ Association.
It was a registered association, its Memorandum of Association
16
provided that one of the objectives was to prtoect common interest and
welfare of LPG cylinder manufacturers. According to COMPAT, there was
a definite platform available for all cylinder manufacturers and practically
all the appllants appear to be the members of that Association.
(C) A common written reply was submitted by as many as 44 parties.
Further, the appellants had nominated six agents for depositing bids on
their behalf. These common agents were instructed to keep a close watch
on the price quoted by the competitors in a particular State.
Though some of the appellants had contended that they had not
appointed the common agents, the plea was not accepted by the
COMPAT. The COMPAT, therefore, proceeded on the ‘admitted grounds’
that there was an association of cyliner manufactures; practically all the
appellants were members of the said association; this association was an
active association; it held meetings on the eve of entry tender obviously for
discussing tenders, its conditions etc.; these meetings were attended by
representatives of at least 19 appellants; and these appellants had six
common agents at Mumbai who were instructed to watch the prices
offered by the others. A dinner meeting as also a munch were held and
one Mr. Chandi Prasad Bhartia of M/s. Haldia Precision Engineering
Private Limited paid the bill for the same. Dinner and lunch held in Sahara
17
hotel were attended by about 50 persons in all. From this the COMPAT
inferred that there was no reason to disbelieve that the parties had an
access to each other through their association which was an active
association. The existence of such an association under the aegis of
which meetings took place just before the submission of tender has been
noted as a very relevant factor by the COMPAT in affirming the findings of
CCI on cartelisation and it summed up the position in the following
manner:
“26. What is important is not whether a particular appellant was a member of the association or not. The existence of an association is by itself sufficient, as it gives opportunity to the competitors to interact with each other and discuss the trade problems. There will be no necessity to prove that any party actually discussed the prices by actively taking part in the meeting. If there is a direct evidence to that effect that is certainly a pointer towards the fact that such party had a tacit agreement with its competitors. However, the existence of an association and further holding of the meetings just one or two days prior to the last date of making offers and further admission that the parties had appointed common agents with the instructions to keep watch on the prices quoted by the competitors would go a long way in providing plus factors in favour of the agreement between the parties. All these factors would form a back drop, in the light of which, the further evidence about agreement would have to be appreciated. We have seen the comments of Director General as also the findings of the CCI. We are convinced that CCI has not committed any error in considering all these factors as plus factors to come to the conclusion that there was a concerted agreement between the parties on the basis of which the identical or near identical prices came to be quoted in tenders for the supply of cylinders to the 25 States. In view of this, we need not dilate on the individual claims by some of the appellants that they were not the members of the association or that they were only the dormant members or that they had abdicated their membership. We also
18
need not go on the claim that while the meeting was attended by the 19 parties as held by the D.G. and confirmed by the CCI, it was not attended by the rest of the appellants because that would be of no consequence. Once there was a meeting, there was every opportunity to discuss or to communicate to each other whatever transpired in the meeting.
27. We have seen the order of the CCI and while commenting about the meeting, the CCI has painstakingly noted the details of that meeting. The CCI has referred to the evidence of Mr. Dinesh Goyal, who was an active member of the Indian LPG Cylinder Manufacturers’ Association and noted that he had attended the meeting. He has also referred to the statement of Mr. Sandeep Bhartia of Carbac Group though initially he denied to have organized the conference, he later on had confirmed about such a conference having been held along with Mr. Sandeep Bhartia of Carbac Group. The CCI also noted that he admitted that in such meetings there were discussions on pre-bid issues. He also admitted that though there are about 50 competitors, in fact about 25 persons control the whole affairs. From this evidence, the CCI correctly deduced that pre-bid issues were discussed in that meeting. The CCI has then referred to the evidence of Mr. Manvinder Singh of Bhiwadi Cylinders Limited, Mr. Chandi Prasad Bhartia of Haldia Precision Engineering P. Ltd., Mr. Vijay Kumar Agarwal of SM Sugar Pvt. Ltd., Mr. S. Kulandhaiswamy, MD of Lite Containers Pvt. Ltd. and Secretary of the Association, Mr. Ramesh Kumar Batra, Director of Surya Shakti Vessels Pvt. Ltd. and on that basis came to the correct conclusion that not only was the meetings held on 1st and 2nd March, but thorough discussions went on in those meeting on the pre-bid issue of the concerned tender. The CCI has also correctly noted about the agenda of the meeting and has also referred to an admission made by one of the witnesses that the matching of the quotation was a matter of co-incidence and telephonic discussions do take place amongst the parties regarding the trends. We are thus thoroughly convinced about holding of the meeting, the discussion held therein and also the discussion regarding the pre-bid issue having been taken place in that meeting.”
16) The COMPAT thereafter took up for discussion the argument of the
appellants that the CCI should have enquired IOCL also. But rejected the
19
same. Another significant argument which was canvassed before us also
with great emphasis was that it was an oligopolistic market wherein there
was a likelihood of each player being aware of actions of the other and in
such a situation price parallelism would be a common phenomena. Thus,
merely because there was a price parallalism, it would not be construed as
evidence of collusion. The COMPAT rejected this argument as well. In
the process, it analysed the order of CCI, conclusion whereof was founded
on the following factors:
(1) The prevailing market conditions were such that there was a
constant demand for cylinders not only by IOCL but by other two oil
manufacutring companies as well. Therefore, there was a constant need
for the cylinders which facilitated factor for the collusion.
(2) There was small number of suppliers. Among the 50 participating
companies, only 37 companies could be said to be independant bidding
companies and there were seven groups consisting of 20 participating
companies. This small number of suppliers should also be a facilitating
factor.
(3) There were very few new entrants.
(4) The existence of an active trade association in which all the bidders,
except seven companies, were members would be another facilitating
20
factor.
(5) Few other factors like repetitive bidding, identical products, few or no
substitutes and no significant technological changes were the additional
factors which persuaded the CCI to arrive at such a conclusion.
(6) These manufacturing companies had their factories at different
places in India, where the costs of the components would differ from State
to State. Even the taxing structure, the labour conditions and other factors
like cost of electricity etc. were bound to be different. Still the prices
quoted were almost identical.
(7) On the above considerations, the defence of the appellants was
rejected as unconvincing, thereby undergoing the factors considered by
the CCI.
17) According to the COMPAT all these could not have been possible
unless there were internal agreements between the appellants. The
COMPAT has approved the finding of the CCI that owing to the collusion,
the IOCL could not get lower or the competitive prices. The rates quoted
in 2010-2011 were higher as compared to the rate quoted in 2009-10.
From the year 2006-07, the prices had collectively been raised on an
average of 30% for making supplies in different states.
18) According to the COMPAT, the CCI was right in concluding that it had
21
appreciable adverse effect on competition as the conduct of the LPG
cylinder manufacturers in coming together on a common platform and
fixing the bid prices ensures that no new player could enter the relevant
market and quote the prices independently. Thus, these manufacturers
would make entry of a new player into the relevant market difficult,
because such new player would necessarily have to first negotiate with the
existing players to get the business profitably. Other factors were driving
existing competitiors out of the market and foreclosure of competition by
hindering entry into the market.
19) It negated the argument of the appellants that when the IOCL was
placing orders on the basis of negotiated rates there could be no
possibility of incentive to collude. According to it, even where the rates are
fixed, the bid rigging can still take place to keep the big amounts to a
pre-determined level. Such pre-determination can be by way of intentional
manipulation by members of the bidding group and where the L-1 rates
themselves get fixed like in the present case at higher level even if there
are negotations the negotiators would have to take into consideration the
benchmark rates. There is aslo a possibility that such benchmark rates
could go higher in the subsequent tenders; known as rippel effect in long
term.
22
20) The COMPAT also took note of the provisions of Section 3, as per
which once the agreement is proved there is a presumption about the
appreciable adverse effect on competition on the mere proof of the
agreement. Thus, onus shifts on the other side to prove otherwise which
according to the COMPAT was not discharged by the appellants. The
COMPAT thereafter took note of some arguments by certain counsel
specific to their cases but did not find any substance in them.
21) Having examined the relevant provisions whereupon these appeals
centre around, we proceed to take note of the arguments that were
advanced by various counsel appearing for the appellants and the manner
in which respondents endeavoured to meet the same.
22) Ms. Madhavi Divan, learned counsel appearing in the appeal filed by
Rajasthan Cylinders and Containers Ltd., attacked the very basis and
foundation on which CCI came to conclusion that there was an agreement
or cartelisation by the appellants aimed at bid rigging. She premised her
case on the following three propositions:
(i) the inherent nature of the market of cylinder manufacturers itself
precludes the possibility of competition;
(ii) alternatively, there is no collusive agreement or bid-rigging in the
present case; and
23
(iii) further, in the alternative, even assuming that there is a collusive
agreement or bid-rigging in the present case, there is no appreciable
adverse effect on competition.
23) On the first proposition, argument developed by Ms. Divan was that
the Act prohibits anti-competitive practices, which would imply that there
has to be a competition in the market, in the first place. As a corrolary, if
there is no such competition, Section 3(1) of the Act does not get
triggered. According to her, in the instant case, the fact would show that
there was a tight control and regulation by the IOCL and, thus, it did not
lead any scope of competition at the very threshold. She stressed that the
conditions of monopsony/oligopsony prevailed. For the existence of
monopsony/oligopsony, she referred to the Glossary of Industrial
Organization Economics and Competition Law published by the
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), as
per which a monopsony consists of a market with a single buyer. When
there are only a few buyers, the market is described as an oligopsony. In
general, when buyers have some influence over the price of their inputs
they are said to have monopsony power. The ability of a firm to raise
prices, even when it is a monopolist, can be reduced or eliminated by
monopsony or oligopsony buyers. To the extent that input prices can be
24
controlled in this way, consumers may be better off.
24) According to her, these conditions were adequately present in the
instant case. In her attempt to make this propositoin good, she highlighed
the following features and conditions surrounding the contract:
(i) Extremely limited number of buyers and for this particular kind of
market - a sole buyer, i.e., IOCL. IOCL controls 48% of the market share.
There are no other purchasers of 14.2 Kg gas cylinders except for HPCL
and BPCL, both of whom invite e-tenders, having a market share of 26%
and 25% respectively.
(ii) The product is standardized and special to the extent that it is tightly
controlled and regulated by the Government and also there are no other
takers for it.
(iii) There are entry barriers in the market. As per the Tender conditions,
only those manufacturers having valid approval from the Chief Controller
of Explosives (CCOE) and Bureau of Indian Standards (BIS) license for
manufacture of 14.2 kg LPG cylinders as per IS-3196 (Part 1) could
submit bids for the tender.
(iv) Even the machinery used to manufacture this product is special and
will become obsolete and reduceable to scrap if IOCL and the aforesaid
two players were to discontinue contracts for supply of 14.2 kg cylinders.
25
She pointed out that this was accepted in the Expert Report of Dr. Rughvir
K.S. Khemani.
(v) The tender conditions state that it can be rejected without furnishing
reasons. Therefore, the lowest price is not sacrosanct (clause 11 of the
contract).
(vi) L2 and L3 have also been granted contracts irrespective of the price
they have quoted.
(vii) Effective price has no sanctity since not only L2 and L3 also get
contracts in addition to or in exclusion of L1 but further, the final negotiated
price is determined on the basis of privately conducted negotiations with
individual bidders for which the benchmark is not the price quoted by them
but the internal estimates arrived on the basis of objective criteria.
(viii) In most States, the final negotiated price was concluded at a rate
lower than the internal estimate. The internal estimate had absolutely no
correlation with the quoted rates by L1 or any other party. In this behalf,
she pointed out that the IOCL had carried out the exercise of ascertaining
the estimated cost of the cylinder through its experts. In the report given
by the expert, the estimated cost per cylinder was arrived at Rs. 1106.61
paisa per cylinder. As against this, the final negotiated price at which the
appellants had supplied cylinders to the IOCL was much lesser. According
26
to her, in the whole process the price determination was on the basis of
internal estimates by IOCL which could not be influenced by the appellants
at all. In fact, even after the tenderers submitted their bids, final price was
the price negotiated by IOCL which fact was accepted by Mr. Y. Ramana
Rao of IOCL in his deposition recorded by the Director General of CCI.
This, according to the learned counsel, clearly proved that there was no
adverse effect on competition, in any case.
(ix) The internal estimates were drawn up long after the price bids were
made, i.e., on 5th May, 2010. Price bids were opened on 23rd March, 2010
and negotiations were held only after the submission of Mott MacDonald
Report on 05.05.2010.
(x) The pattern shows that since L1, L2 and even L3 were awarded the
contract and not merely L1, quoting the lowest price did not even
determine the identity of the parties who were to get the contract,
therefore, the manner in which the process was conducted or controlled
by IOCL, completely leaves no scope for either determination of price or
the identity of the parties who would get the contract.
25) She submitted that in such market conditions where on account of
the vertical agreement there is virtually no scope of competitive forces
between horizontal players, the question of anti-competitive conduct by
27
virture of horizontal agreements does not arise. There is no competition in
the market even before a player enters the fray. Therefore, the first
premise for the applciation of Section 3, i.e., the presence of an otherwise
competitive market is absent. The burden of proof is on the respondent—
CCI to establish that there is competition in the market before it can justify
invoking Section 3. There is no automatic presumption under Section 3
that there is competition in the market.
26) From the aforesaid factors, Ms. Divan tried to deduce that price
control was entirely in the hands of IOCL and in a situation like this,
question of entering into any agreement with the motive of bid rigging or
collusive bidding did not arise.
27) She also referred to LPG (Regulation of Supply and Distribution)
Order, 2000 published vide Notification dated 26th April, 2000 as per which
only Government oil companies can supply LPG to domestic consumer of
14.2 kg LPG cylinders with dimensions as specified therein. Predicated
thereupon, her submission was that the LPG supply in 14.2 kg gas
cylinders is an essential commodity; the distribution of such cylinders
takes place only through Government oil companies; the price to the
consumer is controlled by the Government; and parallel marketeers,
supplier and distributor of LPG cylinders may do so only for cylinders and
28
specifications other than 14.2 kg cylinders. This control of the
Government, insofar as supply of 14.2 kg gas cylinders is concerned,
would also show tight control over the pricing. In such a statutorily tight
control price fixing mechanism there could not be bid rigging, was the
submission of Ms. Divan. She supported this submission by drawing the
attention of the Court to the following observations in Ashoka Smokeless
Coal India (P) Ltd. v. Union of India2 :
“109. It may be true that prices are required to be fixed having regard to the market forces. Demand and supply is a relevant factor as regards fixation of the price. In a market governed by free economy where competition is the buzzword, producers may fix their own price. It is, however, difficult to give effect to the constitutional obligations of a State and the principles leading to a free economy at the same time. A level playing field is the key factor for invoking the new economy. Such a level playing field can be achieved when there are a number of suppliers and when there are competitors in the market enabling the consumer to exercise choices for the purpose of procurement of goods. If the policy of the open market is to be achieved the benefit of the consumer must be kept uppermost in mind by the State.
xxx xxx xxx
127. While fixing a fair and reasonable price in terms of the provisions of the Essential Commodities Act (although the price is not dual), it is essential that price is actually fixed. Such price fixation is necessary in view of the fact that coal is an essential commodity. It is, therefore, vital that price is actually fixed and not kept variable. Fixation of price of coal is of utmost necessity as it is a mineral of grave national importance. Non-availability of coal and consequently, the other products may lead to hardship to a section of citizens. It may entail closure of factories and other industries which in turn would lead to loss to the State exchequer; as they would be deprived of its taxes. It will lead to loss of employment of a
2 (2007) 2 SCC 640
29
large number of employees and would be detrimental to the avowed object of the Central Government to encourage small-scale industries.”
28) She also referred to the following discussion in Excel Crop Care
Limited v. Competition Commission of India & Anr.3:
“52. We are here concerned with parallel behaviour. We are conscious of the argument put forth by Mr Venugopal that in an oligopoly situation parallel behaviour may not, by itself, amount to a concerted practice. It would be apposite to take note of the following observations made by European Court of Justice in Dyestuffs [Imperial Chemical Industries Ltd. v. Commission of European Communities, 1972 ECR 619 (ECJ)] :
“By its very nature, then, the concerted practice does not have all the elements of a contract but may inter alia arise out of coordination which becomes apparent from the behaviour of the participants. Although parallel behaviour may not itself be identified with a concerted practice, it may however amount to strong evidence of such a practice if it leads to conditions of competition which do not respond to the normal conditions of the market, having regard to the nature of the products, the size and number of the undertakings, and the volume of the said market. Such is the case especially where the parallel behaviour is such as to permit the parties to seek price equilibrium at a different level from that which would have resulted from competition, and to crystallise the status quo to the detriment of effective freedom of movement of the products in the [internal] market and free choice by consumers of their suppliers.”
(emphasis supplied)
At the same time, the Court also added that the existence of a concerted practice could be appraised correctly by keeping in mind the following test:
“If the evidence upon which the contested decision is based is considered, not in isolation, but as a whole, account being taken of the specific features of the products in question.”
3 (2017) 8 SCC 47
30
29) The learned counsel also referred to various judgments of other
jurisdictions, primarily that of European Commission and the Court of
Justice of European Union, which we shall discuss at the appropriate
stage.
30) Ms. Divan, also highlighted that in this entire scenario, it was
necessary to have the views of IOCL. However, in a suo motu case, IOCL
was not even served with any notice and therefore no evidence was
elicited from IOCL on the issue whether there was any autnomy left to the
manufacturer in the matter of price determination.
31) She, thus, argued that merely because there was price parallelism, it
could not have been the reason to arrive at a conclusion that there was a
collusive agreement or bid rigging. She submitted that in a monopsonistic
market where there are few buyers, the price is set by the buyers, and the
conditions are such that sellers can predict demand, there is a repetitive
bidding process and the products are identical and specilized, the
likelihood of price parallelism is natural.
32) Further, price parallelism is inevitable where the buyer has a high
degree of control and determines price, quantity, and even the identities of
the awardees at its discretion. Referring to the following discussion in
31
Union of India v. Hindustan Development Corporation4, she argued
that mere identical pricing cannot lead to the conclusion of cartelisation:
“7. [….] (1) There is not enough of material to conclude that M/s H.D.C., Mukand and Bhartiya formed a cartel. Because of mere quoting identical tender offers by the said three manufacturers for which there is some basis, the conclusion that the said manufacturers had formed a cartel does not appear to be correct. However since the offers of the said three tenderers were identical and the price was somewhat lower, the Tender Committee entertained a suspicion that a cartel had been formed and the same got further strengthened by the post-tender attitude of the said manufacturers which further resulted in entertaining the same suspicion by the other authorities in the hierarchy of decision making body including the Minister of Railways. [….]
33) She pointed out that this principle has also been stated in paragraph
17 of the Union of India v. Hindustan Development Coproration5. Her
submission was that identical pricing may be further explained by the fact
that, given the high degree of predictability of prices, bidders may take a
business decision to mirror prices of competitiors in certain States, by
adjusting or averaging prices in others.
34) The learned counsel pointed out that the CCI arrived at an inference
of a collusive agreement based, inter alia, on the presence of
circumstances which have acted as ‘facilitating factors’ for collusion.
These factors which describe the nature of the industry are:
4 (1993) 1 SCC 467 5 (1993) 3 SCC 499
32
(i) Predictability of demand
(ii) Small number of suppliers
(iii) Few new entrants
(iv) Active trade association
(v) Repetitive bidding
(vi) Identical products
(vii) Few or no substitutes
(viii) No significant technological changes, i.e, a standardised
product in repsect of which there has been no change or alteration in
design.
35) Her reply was that these are the characteristics which define the
industry. Yet these very factors are relied upon to come to the consclusion
that there is ‘collusion’ and ‘bid rigging’. She submitted that if the very
nature of the industry is such that there are very small numbers of
suppliers, very few new entrants and a standard product being supplied to
the same party year after year, such factors are beyond the control of the
individual manufacturers and cannot be relied upon as factors to lead to a
presumption that there is collusive conduct. In other words, the very
nature of the industry cannot be used as a factor to presume collusion
because collusion itself requires a state of mind or intent whereas in this
33
case, most of these factors are inherent in the nature of the industry as
described by the CCI itself.
36) Adverting to her 2nd proposition, namely, there was no collusive
agreement or bid rigging in the present case, her submission was that CCI
has relied on a dinner attended by some manufacturers on 1st March, 2010
and a lunch on 2nd March, 2010 as evidence of a price fixing agreement.
Her response was that the factum of meetings of an association by itself
in any case cannot lead to a conclusion of collusion. Likewise, the
COMPAT also upheld that inference based on the factum of the meetings
of the Associaiton. The COMPAT went to the extent of holding that it is
irrelevant whether a particular party was a member of the Association or
not and the existence of Association is by itself sufficient. This approach
was attacked as contrary to the fundamental right to form an association
under Article 19(1)(c)(g) of the Constitution of India.
37) So far as the meetings over dinner and lunch are concerned, both
were hosted by individual members. In the case of the dinner meeting on
1st March, 2010, it was hosted by Mr. C.P. Bhartiya, MD of North India
Wires. The lunch on 2nd March, 2010 was hosted by Mr. Santosh Bhartiya
of Haldia Precision. It is not as if that the Association paid or the expenses
were shared by all members who attended.
34
38) She also submitted that insofar as appellant – Rajasthan Cylinders
and Containers Limited is concerned, no representatives of appellant
attended the said meeting. Further, many other members did not attend
the meeting. Even as per the findings of the Director General, only 12
persons representing 19 parties are said to have attended the meeting.
Her submission was that as per the allegations, 45 persons had entered
into an agreement of cartelisation which should not be established only
with the said meeting which was not attended by all and in fact very few
members.
39) In any case, according to her, it was expressly stated by at least two
persons who attended the meeting that price was not discussed. These
are Mr. Chandi Prasad Bhartia from Haldia Precision and Mr. Manvinder
Singh of Bhiwadi Cylinders Ltd.
40) Her further submission on this aspect was that the inference drawn
on the basis of six agents being nominated for depositing 44 bids was also
misconceived. The CCI holds that ‘this might have held to the possibility
of copying and matching of the rates quoted in the price bids by many
suppliers in a particular state.”
41) The test as laid down in the case of Ahlstrom Osakeyhtio v.
Commission6 is: Is the concertation the only plausible explaination for the 6 31.3.1993, ECJ (paragraph 115, Internal P.1611) (“Woodpulp”)
35
conduct?
“126. Following that analysis, it must be stated that, in this case, concertation is not the only plausible explanation for the parallel conduct. To begin with, the system of price announcements may be regarded as constituting a rational response to the fact that the pulp market constituted a long-term market and to the need felt by both buyers and sellers to limit commercial risks. Further, the similarity in the dates of price announcements may be regarded as a direct result of the high degree of market transparency, which does not have to be described as artificial. Finally, the parallelism of prices and the price trends may be satisfactorily explained by the oligopolistic tendencies of the market and by the specific circumstances prevailing in certain period. Accordingly, the parallel conduct established by the Commission does not constitute evidence of concertation.
This test is not met in the present case for reasons that are enumerated.
42) Her third proposition was that in any case there was no appreciable
adverse effect on competition. She tried to make this submission good by
contending that when industry is an oligopoly, the price parallel or a finding
of identical quoting of price does not by itself lead to the conclusion of a
conerted price. Moreoever, in the instant case, number of entrants had
increased as 12 new entrants submitted their bid for the year 2010-11.
Therefore, the finding of the CCI, upheld by the COMPAT, that there has
been a creation of barriers for new entrants is without any basis.
43) Other counsel who appeared on behalf of the appellants made their
submission almost on the same lines, albeit, with further elaborations on
36
certain aspects, some of which are taken note of hereafter. Mr. Jaiveer
Shergil, who argued for the appellant—Om Containers (C.A. No. 6369 of
2014) submitted that in order to attract the presumption contained in
Section 3(3) about the appreciable adverse effect on competition, in the
first instance, there has to be a finding that there has been an agreement
of the kind set out in Section 3(3)(a) to (d). Since, the allegation against
the appellants was that the agreement resulted in bid rigging and case is
covered under Section 3(3)(d) of the Act, it was necessary that there is a
positive finding to the aforesaid effect, namely, that there was agreement
which had resulted in bid rigging. Accordoing to him, since the definition of
bid rigging in Explanation to Section 3(3) uses the words ‘means’, the
definition is a hard and fast definition and no other meaning can be
assigned to the expression than is put down in the definition, as held in
Punjab Land Developement & Reclamation Corporation Ltd. vs.
Presiding Officer, Labour Court7 in the following words:
“72. The definition has used the word ‘means’. When a statute says that a word or phrase shall “mean”— not merely that it shall “include” — certain things or acts, “the definition is a hard-and-fast definition, and no other meaning can be assigned to the expression than is put down in definition” (per Esher, M.R., Gough v. Gough [(1891) 2 QB 665 : 65 LT 110] ). A definition is an explicit statement of the full connotation of a term.”
7 (1990) 3 SCC 682
37
44) Thus, according to him, for it to be a case of bid rigging, the
agreement must be such which is defined in the Explanation to Section
3(3)(d) creating the effect of:
a. Eliminating or reducing competition for bids or
b. Adversely affecting the process for bidding or
c. Manipulating the process for bidding.
45) He referred to the judgment in S. Sundaram Pillai vs. V.R.
Pattabiraman8, on the purpose of an ‘Explanation’, viz.:
“46. We have now to consider as to what is the impact of the Explanation on the proviso which deals with the question of willful default. Before, however, we embark on an inquiry into this difficult and delicate question, we must appreciate the intent, purpose and legal effect of an Explanation. It is now well settled that an Explanation added to a statutory provision is not a substantive provision in any sense of the term but as the plain meaning of the word itself shows it is merely meant to explain or clarify certain ambiguities which may have crept in the statutory provision. Sarathi in Interpretation of Statutes while dwelling on the various aspects of an Explanation observes as follows:
(a) The object of an Explanation is to understand the Act in the light of the explanation.
(b) It does not ordinarily enlarge the scope of the original section which it explains, but only makes the meaning clear beyond dispute.”
46) He submitted that there is no positive evidence of this nature at all
and the CCI as well as COMPAT has proceeded on inferences as regards
8 (1985) 1 SCC 591
38
bid rigging and, therefore, such orders cannot be sustained.
In the absence thereof, submitted the learned counsel, doctrine of reverse burden which was put on the appellants would not apply. He referred to the following judgments9 in support.
47) The counsel relied upon the following observations in CCI v.
Artistes & Technicians of W.B. Film & Television:
“31. The Competition Act, 2002, as amended in 2007 and 2009, deals with anti-trust issues viz. regulation of anti-competitive agreements, abuse of dominant position and a combination or acquisition falling within the provisions of the said Act. Since the majority view of CCI also accepted that the impugned activities of the Coordination Committee did not amount to abuse of dominant position, and it treated the same as anti-competitive having appreciable adverse effect on competition, our discussion would be focused only on anti-competitive agreements. Section 3 of the Act is the relevant section in this behalf. It is intended to curb or prohibit certain agreements. Therefore, in the first instance, it is to be found out that there existed an “agreement” which was entered into by enterprise or association of enterprises or person or association of persons. Thereafter, it needs to be determined as to whether such an agreement is anti-competitive agreement within the meaning of the Act. Once it is found to be so, other provisions relating to the treatment that needs to be given thereto get attracted.”
48) Taking aid of the aforesaid legal principle, it was submitted that in the
present case it will be seen that the CCI, rather arriving at a finding with
focus on the aforesaid factors, proceeded to analyse factors which attach
to the general market conditions of the industry to ‘infer’ the ‘possibility’ of
bid rigging and then concluded that the ‘facilitating factors’ which may be
‘considered conducive for cartelisation’ are present. The D.G. found that
9
39
‘in all the probability, prices were fixed there at the meeting in Bombay in
collusion with each other. Such an inference and assumption based on
‘higher chances’, ‘probability’, ‘tendencies’ or ‘likelihood’ by the CCI does
not meet the requirement of the definition contained in Explanation to
Section 3(3) and certainly does not constitute a finding of ‘bid rigging’ as
defined therein. The Tribunal has also proceeded on the basis that it ‘is to
be deduced....that these meetings did relate to the tender offers’. There
was, thus, not clearcut, precise and consistent evidence to support that
the alleged bid rigging took place.
49) Next submission of Mr. Shergil was that apart from the complete
absence of a finding of bid rigging, in the present IOCL tender, as a matter
of fact there canot be any bid rigging as defined in Section 3(3). To take
the first ingredient, i.e., eliminating or reducing competition for bids, the
report of D.G. itself finds that out of the 60 bidding parties 37 entities were
not belonging to any single group and are independently controlled.
Hence, straight away there is no case of ‘eliminating or reducing
competition for bids’ which is one of the possible ingredients of bid rigging
as there were 37 entities who were free of mind to participate and bid of
their own accord in the absence of any control by any cartel.
50) As regards the second and third requirement of bid rigging, i.e.,
40
adversely effecting or manipulating the bidding process, he argued that
the submission of bids by the appellant (even if identical) can have no
effect of ‘adversely effecting or manipulating the bidding process’ this
being on account of the very nature of the present tender process.
Although, bids are invited from bidders, IOCL has a fixed/base
procurement price of Rs. 1106.61 per cylinder. IOCL then works out an
estimated rate per State based on certain factors peculiar to that State
such as octroi, freight etc. The bid offered by the L1 (lowest bidder) is then
subject to further downward negotiations by IOCL as per the tender clause
and a further finalised rate is arrived at. Such finalised rate is eventually
even lower10 than the L1 bid amount. Thus, factually, logically and in
reality any bid submitted by any party can never be one which is said to
adversely affect or manipulate the bidding process. All of this information
is with IOCL as part of its bidding process preparations, estimates and
financial workings and could easily have been taken into consideration. In
support, Mr. Shergil also referred to the terms and conditions of the IOCL
tender.
51) His further submission was that CCI, or for that matter COMPAT,
were wrong in getting influenced by the submissions of identical bids by
the appellants as it could not be, ipso facto, inferance of bid rigging. Such 10
41
identical prices could be for various reasons and he shared that the
reasons given by Ms. Divan predicated her submissions on
oligopsony/monopsony. In addition, he relied upon the judgment of this
Court in Union of India vs. Hindustan Development Corporation11 and,
in particular, para 17 thereof, which is as under:
“17. Therefore, whether in a given case, there was formation of a cartel by some of the manufacturers which amounts to an unfair trade practice, depends upon the available evidence and the surrounding circumstances. In the instant case, initially the Tender Committee formed the opinion that the three big manufacturers formed a cartel on the ground that the price initially quoted by them was identical and was only a cartel price. This, in our view, was only a suspicion which of course got strengthened by post-tender attitude of the said manufacturers who quoted a much lesser price. As noticed above it cannot positively be concluded on the basis of these two circumstances alone. In the past these three big manufacturers also offered their own quotations and they were allotted quantities on the basis of the existing practice. However, a mere quotation of identical price and an offer of further reduction by themselves would not entitle them automatically to corner the entire market by way of monopoly since the final allotment of quantities vested in the authorities who in their discretion can distribute the same to all the manufacturers including these three big manufacturers on certain basis. No doubt there was an apprehension that if such predatory price has to be accepted the smaller manufacturers will not be in a position to compete and may result in elimination of free competition. But there again the authorities reserved a right to reject such lower price. Under these circumstances though the attitude of these three big manufacturers gave rise to a suspicion that they formed a cartel but there is not enough of material to conclude that in fact there was such formation of a cartel. However, such an opinion entertained by the concerned authorities including the Minister was not malicious nor was actuated by any extraneous considerations. They entertained a reasonable suspicion based on the record and other
11
42
surrounding circumstances and only acted in a bona fide manner in taking the stand that the three big manufacturers formed a cartel.”
52) Some literature on the ‘theory of oligopolistic interdependence’ as
well as judgments of the European Union and European Commission were
also cited.
53) Mr. Pradeep Aggarwal, in addition, argued that though there was no
positive finding of cartelisation and the conclusion was merely
presumptive, even if it is accepted that there was such an agreement of
bid rigging or collusive bidding, there was no presumption of ‘appreciable
adverse effect on competiiton’. In the alternative, he submitted that there
was, in fact, no appreciable adverse effect on competition in the present
case and the said presumption totally was rebutted by producing sufficient
evidence on record.
54) Various other counsel also argued on the same lines and in addition
referred to facts or their specific cases and it is not necessary to state all
those arguments to avoid repetition.
55) Per contra, Mr. Salman Khurshid, learned senior counsel appearijng
for CCI highlighted the purpose for which the Act is enacted and, in
particular, objective behind Section 3 of the Act, whch is taken note of by
this Court in Excel Crop Care Limited as well as West Bengal Artists
43
Association. Insofar as instant case is concerned, his submission was
that it is a stark and clear-cut case of bid rigging as a result of
anti-competitive agreement amongst LPG manufacturers in respect of a
tender (Tender No. LPG-O/M/PT-03/09-10) floated by IOCL for
procurement of approximately 1,05,00,000 (105 laks) LPG Cylinders. This
is a matter of serious public concern because these cylinders were to be
used to supply Liquefied Petroleum Gas (LPG) for domestic consumption
across 25 States. A rise in price resulting from anti-competitive activities
would affect the cost of living for the common man, and has serious
ramifications for the economy as a whole.
56) Mr. Khurshid referred to the findings of the CCI as approved by
COMPAT and submitted that there was a strong economic evidence of
collusion which is evident from the following aspects:
(a) Identical or near-identical bidding by all 50 empaneled LPG vendors
resulting in bid rigging.
(b) Results of the tender revealed that these bids were made in such a
way that all the bidders were awarded some portion of the tender and no
bidder was left empty handed, i.e., Market Sharing Arrangement.
(c) Geographical/Territorial allocation of market, i.e., the bids were
placed in such a way that entities located in the northern parts of the
44
country were awrded the tender in the northern States, entities located in
the southern parts were awarded the tender in respect of southern States
etc.
(d) No plausible economic rationale or explanation was forthcoming for the
identical bids, despite obvious difference in cost of production, location,
input cost etc.
(e) The overall effect of increase in price of procurement of LPG Cylinders
over previous years.
57) He also submitted that pattern of identical and near identical bids,
which was all pervasive through out, could not be brushed aside lightly as
that was the clear indicator of price bidding as a result of agreement
between the parties. The analysis of the bids also shows that it had
already been decided amongst the LPG Cylinder manufacturers as to who
the L1 and L2 bidders were going to be prior to submission of bids. For
instance, in the State of Punjab, the L1 bidder (Shri Ram Cylinders) bid
Rs. 1080 whereas the four L2 bidders placed identical bids at Rs, 1080.50,
i.e., a difference of only 50 paise from the L-1 bid. Similarly, in Rajasthan,
the L-1 bidder (M/s. Rajasthan Cylinders) quoted Rs. 1130, whereas nine
L2 bidders quoted identically by just 50 paise more, at Rs. 1130.50. This
pattern is repeated across a number of States.
45
58) Not only this, in order to achieve the pre-decided outcome, some of
the bidders hastily made corrections to their bid documents. One such
case is that of M/s. Jesmajo Industrial Fabrications (appellant in C.A. No.
4868 of 2014). In the bid documents, the bid of Rs. 1103 was
cut-corrected to make it Rs. 1103.60 even though the calculation of VAT
was done only on the figure of |Rs. 1103. The Director General has
commented on this aspect as follows:
“6.13…...That bids were submitted after mutual discussion is apparent from the tender documents of Jesmajo Industrial Fabricators P. Ltd. (Exhibit 4P). There are cuttings in the tender documents and financial bids of the company. Since, there were discussions among all oil companies, the company might have decided to make alterations in the financial bids. However, even in the financial bids of the company, it is noted that despite alterations, errors have remained. It seems that the company had originally quoted Rs. 1103/- as the rate. Subsequently it changed the rates to Rs. 1103.60. However, VAT rate in the bid had been calculated on Rs. 1103/- only instead of Rs. 1103.60. Thus, while other component of rates has been changed/altered, the calculation of VAT has been done on Rs. 1103 (originally quoted) instead of Rs. 1103.60 (altered quote). This appears to have been done to match rates with other bidders who have quoted the similar rates in the State of Karnataka and to let Sanghvi group be L-1 in that State.”
59) Mr. Khurshid also refuted the submisison of the appellants that there
was no competition and, therefore, Section 3 was not applicable.
According to him, if the matters are examined on such basis most of the
culprits will get away. The purpose of the Act was not only to eliminate
cartelisation but also to promote competition. His submission was that
46
once the findings of the CCI and COMPAT are accepted that there was an
agreement, such an agreement was obviously for the purpose of curbing
the competition.
60) Answering the argument of ‘price parallelism’ which according to the
appellants resulted in identical and near identical bids, Mr. Khurshid
argued that legal submission in this respect was settled by this Court in
Excel Crop Care case wherein such an argument was rejected in the
following words:
“48…It was argued that since dominant position is enjoyed by the buyer, it leads to parallel pricing and this conscious parallelism takes place leading to quoting the same price by the suppliers. The explanation, thus, given for quoting identical price was the aforesaid economic forces and not because of any agreement or arrangement between the parties. It was submitted that merely because same price was quoted by the appellants in respect of the 2009 FCI tender, one could not jump to the conclusion that there was some “agreement” as well between these parties, in the absence of any other evidence corroborating the said factum of quoting identical price. In respect of this submission, Mr Venugopal had also referred to a few judgments.
49. The aforesaid argument is highly misconceived. A neat and pellucid reply of Mr. Kaul, which commands acceptance, is that argument of parallelism is not applicable in bid cases and it fits in the realm of market economy. It is for this reason that entire history of quoting identical price before coming into operation of Section 3 and which continued much after Section 3 of the Act was enforced, has been highlighted...”
61) He also referred to the following findings of COMPAT with the
submission that finding of facts need to be accepted:-
47
“36. We are thoroughly convinced by this analysis that all this could not have been possible unless there were internal agreements between the concerns. What shocks us is that the quotations of the price did match to the last decimal and the quotations in some cases were in odd figures like Rs.1127 in the State of Tamil Nadu. The record is replete with such odd figures. It was strange that in some of the oral statements of the representatives of these parties, who were examined by the DG, some of them could not even justify these identical prices and tried to say that it was a mere coincidence. We cannot accept the argument of coincidence as was rightly rejected by CCI. There can be no explanation for this kind of identical or near identical pricing. The CCI has rightly considered that the manufacturing cost of per cylinder varies in a wide spectrum ranging from Rs.870 to Rs.1095.89. If this was the case, the prices had to be different, if they had been offered in a competitive spirit. Either before the CCI or before us no material was produced, which would be able to rebut the presumption arising from the identity of rates. The CCI, therefore, rightly concluded that this identity of prices was sinister and anti-competitive in nature.”
62) Another feature which Mr. Salman Khurshid pointed out was that the
analysis of bids revealed that there was a market sharing and territorial
allocation of bids. This, according to him, could be discerned from the
following evidence emerging from record:
“Firstly, the economic evidence indicates that there was an understanding or arrangement or agreement by which each and every bidder would get some part of the allocation under the tender. This is clear from the fact that each and every one of the 50 bidders who submitted price bids received some part of the allocation in one or more states, and no one went empty handed. In other words, the purpose of quoting identical bids in many instances was to achieve the objective of sharing the market, i.e., the IOCL requirement across 25 states was ‘shared’ by each of the 50 bidders, through concerted action and pre-decided understanding.
48
63) Mr. Khurshid also highlighed that in spite of there being difference in
location of appellant’s units and their input cost, the bids submitted by
various tenderers were identical and there canot be any plausible
economic rationale for such identical bidding. Therefore, the inference
drawn by the CCI as well as COMPAT based on the aforesaid features
and factors was justified and valid in law. He also referred to certain
judgements of this Court as well as other jurisdictions, such as, European
Commission and the Court of Justice of European Union to which
reference would be made at the appropriate stage.
64) Before we deal with the arguments advanced by various counsel
who appeared for the appellants and rebuttal thereto by Mr. Salman
Khurshid, learned senior counsel who appeared for CCI as also counsel
for IOCL, we would like to reproduce the relevant provisions of the Act in
the light of which these appeals are to be decided:
65) Section 2(c) defines “cartel” and reads as under:
“”Cartel” includes an association of producers, sellers, distributors, traders or service providers who, by agreement amongst themselves, limit, control or attempt to control the production, distribution, sale or price of, or, trade in goods or provision of services;
66) Section 3 of the Act deals with and prohibits those agreements which
49
cause and are likely to cause an appreciable adverse effect on
competition within india. It reads as under:
“Section 3 : Anti-competitive agreements:-
(1) No enterprise or association of enterprises or person or association of persons shall enter into any agreement in respect of production, supply, distribution, storage, acquisition or control of goods or provision of services, which causes or is likely to cause an appreciable adverse effect on competition within India.
(2) Any agreement entered into in contravention of the provisions contained in sub-section (1) shall be void.
(3) Any agreement entered into between enterprises or associations of enterprises or persons or associations of persons or between any person and enterprise or practice carried on, or decision taken by, any association of enterprises or association of persons, including cartels, engaged in identical or similar trade of goods or provision of services, which—
(a) directly or indirectly determines purchase or sale prices;
(b) limits or controls production, supply, markets, technical development, investment or provision of services;
(c) shares the market or source of production or provision of services by way of allocation of geographical area of market, or type of goods or services, or number of customers in the market or any other similar way;
(d) directly or indirectly results in bid rigging or collusive bidding, shall be presumed to have an appreciable adverse effect on competition: Provided that nothing contained in this sub-section shall apply to any agreement entered into by way of joint ventures if such agreement increases efficiency in production, supply, distribution, storage, acquisition or control of goods or provision of services.
50
Explanation.—For the purposes of this sub-section, "bid rigging" means any agreement, between enterprises or persons referred to in sub-section (3) engaged in identical or similar production or trading of goods or provision of services, which has the effect of eliminating or reducing competition for bids or adversely affecting or manipulating the process for bidding.”
67) Certain factors are mentioned in Section 19 of the Act which have to
be kept in mind while determining whether an agreement has an
appreciable adverse effect on competition under Section 3. We reproduce
this Section hereinbelow:
“Section 19(3) in the Competition Act, 2002:
(3) The Commission shall, while determining whether an agreement has an appreciable adverse effect on competition under section 3, have due regard to all or any of the following factors, namely:—
(a) creation of barriers to new entrants in the market;
(b) driving existing competitors out of the market;
(c) foreclosure of competition by hindering entry into the market;
(d) accrual of benefits to consumers;
(e) improvements in production or distribution of goods or provision of services;
(f) promotion of technical, scientific and economic development by means of production or distribution of goods or provision of services.”
68) In Excel Crop Care Limited, scope of Section 3 of the Act which
prohibits three kinds of practices as anti-competitive, was taken note of as
51
follows:
“20. Chapter II of the Act deals with three kinds of practices which are treated as anti-competitive and prohibited. These are: (a) where agreements are entered into by certain persons with a view to cause an appreciable adverse effect on competition; (b) where any enterprise or group of enterprises, which enjoys dominant position, abuses the said dominant position; and
(c) regulating the combination of enterprises by means of mergers or amalgamations to ensure that such mergers or amalgamations do not become anti-competitive or abuse the dominant position which they can attain.”
69) In that case also the Court was concerned with the 1st category,
namely, those cases where certain persons enter into agreements with a
view to cause an appreciable adverse effect of competition. Purpose
behind curbing such anti-competitive practices was mentioned in detail. It
is not necessary to re-state the same in that expansive manner, however,
we would still like to quote certain portions to capture the essence and
purpose of the Act:-
“21. In the instant case, we are concerned with the first type of practices, namely, anti-competitive agreements. The Act, which prohibits anti-competitive agreements, has a laudable purpose behind it. It is to ensure that there is a healthy competition in the market, as it brings about various benefits for the public at large as well as economy of the nation. In fact, the ultimate goal of competition policy (or for that matter, even the consumer policies) is to enhance consumer well-being. These policies are directed at ensuring that markets function effectively. Competition policy towards the supply side of the market aims to ensure that
52
consumers have adequate and affordable choices. Another purpose in curbing anti-competitive agreements is to ensure “level playing field” for all market players that helps markets to be competitive. It sets “rules of the game” that protect the competition process itself, rather than competitors in the market. In this way, the pursuit of fair and effective competition can contribute to improvements in economic efficiency, economic growth and development of consumer welfare………..
xxx xxx xxx
23. In fact, there is broad empirical evidence supporting the proposition that competition is beneficial for the economy. Economists agree that it has an important role to play in improving productivity and, therefore, the growth prospects of an economy…..
24. Productivity is increased through competition by putting pressure on firms to control costs as the producers strive to lower their production costs so that they can charge competitive prices. It also improves the quality of their goods and services so that they correspond to consumers' demands.
xxx xxx xxx
26. When we recognise that competition has number of benefits, it clearly follows that cartels or anti-competitive agreements cause harm to consumers by fixing prices, limiting outputs or allocating markets. Effective enforcement against such practices has direct visible effects in terms of reduced prices in the market and this is also supported by various empirical studies.
xxx xxx xxx
27. Keeping in view the aforesaid objectives that need to be achieved, Indian Parliament enacted the Competition Act, 2002. Need to have such a law became all the more important in the wake of liberalisation and privatisation as it was found that the law prevailing at that time, namely, Monopolies and Restrictive Trade Practices Act, 1969 was not equipped adequately enough to tackle the competition aspects of the Indian economy. The law enforcement agencies, which include CCI and COMPAT, have to ensure that these objectives are fulfilled by curbing anti-competitive agreements.”
53
70) The Court also mentioned, in particular, that competition leads to
economic efficiency, economic growth and development as well as
consumers welfare. The Court also spelled out the manner in which
competition contributed to increase economic growth and increased
productivity.
71) It follows from the above that whereas on the one hand the
economic policy of the nation has ushered in the era of liberalisation and
globalisation thereby giving freeplay to the private sector in the manner of
conducting business, at the same time, in public interest and in the interest
of consumers, a regime of regulators has also been brought to ensure
certain checks and balances. Since competition among the enterprises or
businessmen is treated as service for a public purpose and, therefore,
there is a need to curb anti-competitive practices, the CCI is given the task
(as a regulator) to ensure that no such anti-competitive practices are
undertaken. In fact, Section 18 of the Act casts a specific and positive
obligation on CCI to ‘eliminate’ anti-competitive practices and promote
competition, interest of the consmuer and free trade. This objective was
also emphasised by this Court in Competition Commission of India vs.
Steel Authority of India Limited and Another12 which can be found in 12
54
the following observations:
“6. As far as the objectives of competition laws are concerned, they vary from country to country and even within a country they seem to change and evolve over the time. However, it will be useful to refer to some of the common objectives of competition law. The main objective of competition law is to promote economic efficiency using competition as one of the means of assisting the creation of market responsive to consumer preferences. The advantages of perfect competition are threefold: allocative efficiency, which ensures the effective allocation of resources, productive efficiency, which ensures that costs of production are kept at a minimum and dynamic efficiency, which promotes innovative practices. These factors by and large have been accepted all over the world as the guiding principles for effective implementation of competition law.”
72) As mentioned above, one of the anti-competitive practices is
cartelisation, the essential postulate whereof is agreement between
enterprises or association of enterprises or persons or associations of
persons in respect of production, supply, distribution, storage, acquisition
or control of goods or provisions of service, which causes or is likely to
cause an appreciable adverse effect on competition within India. Such an
agreement is treated as void. The types of agreement which may fall foul
of Section 3 are mentioned in sub-section (3) thereof. These include
sharing the market by way of allocation of geographical areas of market
[clause (c)] and the agreements which result in bid-rigging or collusive
bidding whether directly or indirectly [clause (d)]. There is a presumption
that four types of agreements mentioned in sub-section (3) will have an
55
appreciable adverse effect on competition.
73) We may also state at this stage that Section 19(3) of the Act
mentions the factors which are to be examined by the CCI while
determining whether an agreement has an appreciable adverse effect on
competition under Section 3. However, this inquiry would be needed in
those cases which are not covered by clauses (a) to (d) of sub-section (3)
of Section 3. Reason is simple. As already pointed out above, the
agreements of nature mentioned in sub-section (3) are presumed to have
an appreciable effect and, therefore, no further exercise is needed by the
CCI once a finding is arrived at that a particular agreement fell in any of
the aforesaid four categories. We may hasten to add, however, that
agreements mentioned in Section 3(3) raise a presumption that such
agreements shall have an appreciable adverse effect on competition. It
follows, as a fortiorari, that the presumption is rebuttable as these
agreements are not treated as conclusive proof of the fact that it would
result in appreciable adverse effect on competition. What follows is that
once the CCI finds that case is covered by one or more of the clauses
mentioned in sub-section (3) of Section 3, it need not undertake any
further enquiry and burden would shift upon such enterprises or persons
etc. to rebut the said presumption by leading adequate evidence. In case
56
such an evidence is led, which dispels the presumption, then the CCI shall
take into consideration the factors mentioned in Section 19 of the Act and
to see as to whether all or any of these factors are established. If the
evidence collected by the CCI leads to one or more or all factors
mentioned in Section 19(3), it would again be treated as an agreement
which may cause or is likely to cause an appreciable adverse effect of
competition, thereby compelling the CCI to take further remedial action in
this behalf as provided under the Act. That, according to us, is the broad
scheme when Sections 3 and 19 are to be read in conjuction.
74) In these appeals, the Court is concerned with the alleged agreement
entered into between the appellants falling in clause (d) of sub-section (3)
of Section 3, which talks of bid rigging or collusive bidding. Therefore, it
would be necessary to understand the meaning of the expression ‘bid
rigging’ and ‘collusive bidding’. Explanation to Section 3, which is
reproduced, assigns meaning to ‘bid rigging’ and states :
“S. 3:
Explanation.—For the purposes of this sub-section, "bid rigging" means any agreement, between enterprises or persons referred to in sub-section (3) engaged in identical or similar production or trading of goods or provision of services, which has the effect of eliminating or reducing competition for bids or adversely affecting or manipulating the process for bidding.”
57
75) The necessary ingredients of bid rigging, thus, are: (a) agreement
between the parties; (b) these parties are engaged in idential or similar
production or trading of goods or provisions of services; and (c) the
agreement has the effect of eliminating or reducing competition of bids or
adversely affect or manipulating the process for bidding.
76) Though the expression ‘collusive bidding’ is not defined in the Act, it
appears that both ‘bid rigging’ and ‘collusive bidding’ are overlapping
concepts. This position stands accepted in Excel Crop Care Limited
case which should be found from the following discussion therefrom:
“38. Mr Neeraj Kishan Kaul, learned Additional Solicitor General, refuted the aforesaid submission with vehemence by urging that bid rigging and collusive bidding are not mutually exclusive and these are overlapping concepts. Illustratively, he referred to the findings of CCI, as approved by COMPAT, in the instant case itself to the effect that the appellants herein had “manipulated the process of bidding” on the ground that bids were submitted on 8-5-2009 collusively, which was only the beginning of the anti-competitive agreement between the parties and this continued through the opening of the price bids on 1-6-2009 and thereafter negotiations on 17-6-2009 when all the parties reduced their bids by same figure of Rs 2 to bring their bid down to Rs 386 per kg from Rs 388 per kg. From this example, he submitted that on 8-5-2009 there was a collusive bidding but with concerted negotiations on 17-6-2009, in the continued process, it was rigging of the bid that was practiced by the appellants. We are inclined to agree with this pellucid submission of the learned Additional Solicitor General.
39. Richard Whish and David Bailey [Competition Law, 7th Edn., p. 536.] , in their book, have given illustrations of various forms of collusive bidding/bid rigging, which include:
(a) Level tendering/bidding (i.e. bidding at same price — as in the present case).
58
(b) Cover bidding/courtesy bidding.
(c) Bid rotation.
(d) Bid allocation.
40. Even internationally, “collusive bidding” is not understood as being different from “bid rigging”. These two expressions have been used interchangeably in the following international commentaries/glossaries and websites of competition authorities:
(a) UNCTAD Competition Glossary dated 22-6-2016
“Bid rigging or collusive tendering is a manner in which conspiring competitors may effectively raise prices where business contracts are awarded by means of soliciting competitive bids. Essentially, it relates to a situation where competitors agree in advance who will win the bid and at what price, undermining the very purpose of inviting tenders which is to procure goods or services on the most favourable prices and conditions.”
(b) OECD Glossary of Industrial Organisation Economics and Competition Law
“Bid rigging is a particular form of collusive price-fixing behaviour by which firms coordinate their bids on procurement or project contracts. There are two common forms of bid rigging. In the first, firms agree to submit common bids, thus eliminating price competition. In the second, firms agree on which firm will be the lowest bidder and rotate in such a way that each firm wins an agreed upon number or value of contracts.
Since most (but not all) contracts open to bidding involve Governments, it is they who are most often the target of bid rigging. Bid rigging is one of the most widely prosecuted forms of collusion.”
Collusive bidding (tendering) — See “bid rigging”.
(This shows collusive bidding and bid rigging are treated as one and the same.)
(c) OECD Guidelines for fighting bid rigging
59
“Bid rigging (or collusive tendering) occurs when businesses, that would otherwise be expected to compete, secretly conspire to raise prices or lower the quality of goods or services for purchasers who wish to acquire products or services through a bidding process.”
(d) United States Office of the Inspector General, Investigations (Fraud Indicators Handbook)
“Collusive bidding, price fixing or bid rigging, are commonly used interchangeable terms which describe many forms of an illegal anti-competitive activity. The common thread throughout all these activities is that they involve any agreements or informal arrangements among independent competitors, which limit competition. Agreements among competitors which violate the law include but are not limited to:
(1) Agreements to adhere to published price lists. (2) Agreements to raise prices by a specified increment.(3) Agreements to establish, adhere to, or eliminate discounts. (4) Agreements not to advertise prices. (5) Agreements to maintain specified price differentials based on quantity, type or size of product.”
(e) Australian Competition and Consumer Commission
“Bid rigging, also referred to as collusive tendering, occurs when two or more competitors agree they will not compete genuinely with each other for tenders, allowing one of the cartel members to ‘win’ the tender. Participants in a bid rigging cartel may take turns to be the ‘winner’ by agreeing about the way they submit tenders, including some competitors agreeing not to tender.”
41. As the Liegeman of the law, it is our task, nay a duty, to give proper meaning and effect to the aforesaid “Explanation”. It can easily be discussed that the legislature had in mind that the two expressions are interchangeably used. It is also necessary to keep in mind the purport behind Section 3 and the objective it seeks to achieve:
41.1. Sub-section (1) of Section 3 is couched in the negative terms which mandates that no enterprise or association of enterprises or person or association of persons shall enter into any agreement,
60
when such agreement is in respect of production, supply, distribution, storage, acquisition or control of goods or provision of services and it causes or is likely to cause an appreciable adverse effect on competition within India. It can be discerned that first part relates to the parties which are prohibited from entering into such an agreement and embraces within it persons as well as enterprises thereby signifying its very wide coverage. This becomes manifest from the reading of the definition of “enterprise” in Section 2(h) and that of “person” in Section 2(l) of the Act. The second part relates to the subject-matter of the agreement. Again it is very wide in its ambit and scope as it covers production, supply, distribution, storage, acquisition or control of goods or provision of services. The third part pertains to the effect of such an agreement, namely, “appreciable adverse effect on competition”, and if this is the effect, purpose behind this provision is not to allow that. Obvious purpose is to thwart any such agreements which are anti-competitive in nature and this salubrious provision aims at ensuring healthy competition. Sub-section (2) of Section 3 specifically makes such agreements as void.
41.2. Sub-section (3) mentions certain kinds of agreements which would be treated as ipso facto causing appreciable adverse effect on competition. It is in this backdrop and context that “Explanation” beneath sub-section (3), which uses the expression “bid rigging”, has to be understood and given an appropriate meaning. It could never be the intention of the legislature to exclude “collusive bidding” by construing the expression “bid rigging” narrowly. No doubt, clause (d) of sub-section (3) of Section 3 uses both the expressions “bid rigging” and “collusive bidding”, but the Explanation thereto refers to “bid rigging” only. However, it cannot be said that the intention was to exclude “collusive bidding”. Even if the Explanation does contain the expression “collusive bidding” specifically, while interpreting clause (d), it can be inferred that “collusive bidding” relates to the process of bidding as well. Keeping in mind the principle of purposive interpretation, we are inclined to give this meaning to “collusive bidding”. It is more so when the expressions “bid rigging” and “collusive bidding” would be overlapping, under certain circumstances which was conceded by the learned counsel for the appellants as well.
42. We are, therefore, of the opinion that the two expressions are to be interpreted using the principle of noscitur a sociis i.e. when two or more words which are susceptible to analogous meanings are
61
coupled together, the words can take colour from each other. (See Leelabai Gajanan Pansare v. Oriental Insurance Co. Ltd. [Leelabai Gajanan Pansare v. Oriental Insurance Co. Ltd., (2008) 9 SCC 720] , Thakorlal D. Vadgama v. State of Gujarat [Thakorlal D. Vadgama v. State of Gujarat, (1973) 2 SCC 413 : 1973 SCC (Cri) 835] and M.K. Ranganathan v. State of Madras[M.K. Ranganathan v. State of Madras, (1955) 2 SCR 374 : AIR 1955 SC 604] .)”
77) The first proposition of Ms. Divan, viz. there is no competition, has
two facets. First, the legal one which concerns the jurisdiction of the CCI
to deal with such matters and the other is factual, which is to be examined
on the basis of facts in these cases. Insofar as the first component is
concerned, having regard to the aforesaid scheme of the Act, we are not
convinced with the argument of Ms. Madhavi Divan that there is no
possibility of a competition in these cases and, therefore, CCI had no
jurisdiction to carry out any such investigation. The scope and ambit of
the provisions of Section 3 have been considered in detail in Excel Crop
Care Limited case. This Section prohibits anti-competitive agreements
and brings about the prime objective of the Competition Act. These
aspects were noted in Excel Crop Care Limited, relevant portions
whereof are already extracted above. We may also quote the following
portion from the judgment of this Court in Steel Authority of India
Limited wherein objective behind the Act was highlighted in the following
manner:
62
“125. We have already noticed that the principal objects of the Act, in terms of its Preamble and the Statement of Objects and Reasons, are to eliminate practices having adverse effect on the competition, to promote and sustain competition in the market, to protect the interest of the consumers and ensure freedom of trade carried on by the participants in the market, in view of the economic developments in the country. In other words, the Act requires not only protection of free trade but also protection of consumer interest. The delay in disposal of cases, as well as undue continuation of interim restraint orders, can adversely and prejudicially affect the free economy of the country. Efforts to liberalise the Indian economy to bring it on a par with the best of the economies in this era of globalisation would be jeopardised if time-bound schedule and, in any case, expeditious disposal by the Commission is not adhered to. The scheme of various provisions of the Act which we have already referred to including Sections 26, 29, 30, 31, 53-B(5) and 53-T and Regulations 12, 15, 16, 22, 32, 48 and 31 clearly show the legislative intent to ensure time-bound disposal of such matters.”
78) We would like to reemphasise that the purpose of the Act is not only
to illuminate practices having adverse effect on the competition but also to
promote and sustain competition in the market. Enforcement provides
remedies to avoid situation that will lead to decrease competition in the
market. Therefore, effective enforcement is important not only to sanction
anti-competitive conduct but also to deter future competitive practices. In
the present case itself, there are sixty suppliers of the product for which
there are three buyers. After all, each supplier would like to be L-1 or L-2
so that it is able to get order for larger quantities than the other. In this
sense, there would be a competition among them. Further, it would also
be in the interest of the buyers like IOCL etc. that the elements of healthy
63
competition persists in the market. In any case, it is the duty of the CCI to
ensure that the conditions which have tendency to kill the competition are
to be curbed. It is also the function of the CCI to ensure that there is a
competition so that benefits of such competition are reaped by the
consumers. However, insofar as certain factual aspects highlighted by the
appellants are concerned, they would be dealt with while examining the
third proposition, as we deem it more appropriate to discuss these two
aspects together.
79) Second proposition of Ms. Divan was that there was no collusive
bidding in the present case. The CCI and COMPAT have rejected this
argument in view of the fact that there is an active trade association of the
suppliers; a meeting took place couple of days before the date of bidding;
common changes were pointed out by these appellants who submitted
bids on their behalf; and bids were of identical amounts despite varying
cost, which were repetitive in nature. The respondents may be right in
their submission that there may not be a direct evidence on the basis of
which cartalisation or such agreement between the parties can be proved
as these arguments are normally entered into in closed doors. The
standard of proof which is required is one of probability, which is a
principle accepted in Technip SA vs. SMS Holding (P) Ltd. & Ors.13
13
64
wherein the Court stated and discussed this aspect in the following
manner:
“54. The standard of proof required to establish such concert is one of probability and may be established
“if having regard to their relation etc., their conduct, and their common interest, that it may be inferred that they must be acting together: evidence of actual concerted acting is normally difficult to obtain, and is not insisted upon” [CIT v. East Coast Commercial Co. Ltd., (1967) 1 SCR 821 : AIR 1967 SC 768] . (SCR p. 829 H)
55. While deciding whether a company was one in which the public were substantially interested within the meaning of Section 23-A of the Income Tax Act, 1922 this Court said:
“The test is not whether they have actually acted in concert but whether the circumstances are such that human experience tells us that it can safely be taken that they must be acting together. It is not necessary to state the kind of evidence that will prove such concerted actings. Each case must necessarily be decided on its own facts.” [CIT v. Jubilee Mills Ltd., (1963) 48 ITR 9 (SC), p. 20]
56. In Guinness PLC and Distillers Co. PLC [Guinness PLC and Distillers Company PLC (Panel hearing on 25-8-1987 and 2-9-1987 at p. 10052 — Reasons for decisions of the Panel.)] the question before the Takeover Panel was whether Guinness had acted in concert with Pipetec when Pipetec purchased shares in Distillers Company PLC. Various factors were taken into consideration to conclude that Guinness had acted in concert with Pipetec to get control over Distillers Company. The Panel said:
“The nature of acting in concert requires that the definition be drawn in deliberately wide terms. It covers an understanding as well as an agreement, and an informal as well as a formal arrangement, which leads to cooperation to purchase shares to acquire control of a company. This is necessary, as such arrangements are often informal, and the understanding may arise from a hint. The understanding may be tacit, and the definition covers situations where the parties act on the basis of a ‘nod or a wink’…. Unless persons declare this agreement or understanding, there is rarely direct evidence of action in
65
concert, and the Panel must draw on its experience and common sense to determine whether those involved in any dealings have some form of understanding and are acting in cooperation with each other.” [Guinness PLC and Distillers Company PLC (Panel hearing on 25-8-1987 and 2-9-1987 at p. 10052 — Reasons for decisions of the Panel.)]
80) We would also like to reproduce the following discussion in
Commissioner of Income Tax, Bombay City I, Bombay vs. Jubilee
Mills Ltd., Bombay14:
“19. At the hearing a point was raised that it has to be proved as a fact that the persons constituting the group which owns shares carrying more than seventy-five per cent of the voting power, were acting in unison. The test is not whether they have actually acted in concert but whether the circumstances are such that human experience tells us that it can safely be taken that they must be acting together. It is not necessary to state the kind of evidence that will prove such concerted actings. Each case must necessarily be decided on its own facts. The exclusion of “public” in the manner indicated generally from more than 75% of the shares and the concentration of such a holding in a single person or a group acting in concert is what attracts Section 23(A).”
81) It is also significant to state that respondents had drawn attention of
this Court to OECD Policy Roundtables Prosecuting Cartels without Direct
Evidence 2006 which discussed the nature of evidence that is required for
proving cartel agreement, relevant portion thereof contained in para 2 of
the said Policy is reproduced below:
“Available evidence for proving cartel agreements
2.1 Categories of evidence 14
66
Evidence used to prove a cartel agreement can be classified into two types: direct and circumstantial. Circumstantial evidence, in turn, consists of “communication” evidence and economic evidence, which include firm conduct, market structure, and evidence of facilitating practices.
Common types of direct evidence include:
- A document or documents (including email messages) essentially embodying the agreement, or parts of it, and identifying the parties to it.
- Oral or written statements by co-operative cartel participants describing the operation of the cartel and their participation in it.
There are different types of circumstantial evidence. One is evidence that cartel operators met or otherwise communicated but does not describe the substance of their communications. It might be called communication evidence for purposes of this discussion. It includes:
- Records of telephone conversations between competitors (but not their substance), or of travel to a common destination or of participation in a meeting, for example during a trade conference.
- other evidence that the parties communicated about the subject e.g., minutes or notes of a meeting showing that prices, demand or capacity utilisation were discussed; internal documents evidencing knowledge or understanding of a competitors pricing strategy, such as an awareness of a future price increase by a rival.
A broader category of circumstantial evidence is often called economic evidence. Economic evidence identifies primarily firm conduct that suggests that an agreement was reached, but also conduct of the industry as a whole, elements of market structure which suggest that secret price fixing was feasible, and certain practices that can be used to sustain a cartel agreement.
Conduct evidence is the single most important type of economic evidence. As noted earlier, observation of certain, suspicious conduct frequently triggers an investigation of a possible cartel. And as the section in this paper on economics highlights 11 careful
67
analysis of the conduct of parties is important to identify behaviours that can be characterised as contrary to the parties’ unilateral self-interest and which therefore supports the inference of an agreement. Conduct evidence includes, first and foremost:
- Parallel pricing – changes in prices by rivals that are identical, or nearly so, and simultaneous, or nearly so. It includes other forms of parallel conduct, such as capacity reductions, adoption of standardised terms of sale, and suspicious bidding patterns, e.g., a predictable rotation of winning bidders.
Industry performance could also be described as conduct evidence. It includes:
- abnormally high profits; - stable market shares - A history of competition law violations.
Evidence related to market structure can be used primarily to make the finding of a cartel agreement more plausible, even though market structure factors do not prove the existence of such an agreement. Relevant economic evidence relating to market structure includes:
- high concentration; - low concentration on the opposite side of the market; - high barriers to entry; - high degree of vertical integration; - Standardised or homogeneous product.
The evidentiary value of structural evidence can be limited, however. There can be highly concentrated industries selling homogeneous products in which all parties compete. Conversely, the absence of such evidence cannot be used to show that a cartel did not exist. Cartels are known to have existed in industries with numerous competitors and differentiated products.
A specific kind of economic conduct evidence is facilitating practices – practices that can make it easier for competitors to reach or sustain an agreement. It is important to note that conduct described as facilitating practices is not necessarily unlawful. But where a competition authority has found other circumstantial evidence
68
pointing to the existence of a cartel agreement, the existence of facilitating practices can be an important complement. They can explain what kind of arrangements the parties set up to facilitate the formation of a cartel agreement, monitoring, detection of defection, and/or punishment, thus supporting the ‘collusion story’ put together by the competition law enforcer. Facilitating practices include:
- information exchanges; - price signalling; - freight equalisation; - price protection and most favoured nation policies; - Unnecessarily restrictive product standards.”
82) Thus, even in the absence of proof of concluded formal agreement,
when there are indicators that there was practical cooperation between the
parties which knowingly substitute the risk of competition, that would
amount to anti-competitive practices. This has been discussed in
Coordination Committee of Artistes and Technicians of West Bengal
Film and Television & Ors. (see paras 44 and 45). Then, there are
guidelines on the applicability of Article 101 of the Treaty on the
functioning of the E.U. to horizontal cooperation agreements which
records as under:
“60. Information exchange can only be addressed under Article 101 if it establishes or is part of an agreement, a concerted practice or a decision by an association of undertakings. The existence of an agreement, a concerted practice or decision by an association of undertakings does not prejudge whether the agreement, concerted practice or decision by an association of undertakings gives rise to a restriction of competition within the meaning of Article 101(1). In line with the case-law of the Court of Justice of the European Union, the concept of a concerted practice refers to a form of coordination between undertakings by which, without it having reached the stage
69
where an agreement properly so-called has been concluded, practical cooperation between them is knowingly substituted for the risks of competition. The criteria of coordination and cooperation necessary for determining the existence of a concerted practice, far from requiring an actual plan to have been worked out, are to be understood in the light of the concept inherent in the provisions of the Treaty on competition, according to which each company must determine independently the policy which it intends to adopt on the internal market and the conditions which it intends to offer to its customers.
61. This does not deprive companies of the right to adapt themselves intelligently to the existing or anticipated conduct of their competitors. It does, however, preclude any direct or indirect contact between competitors, the object or effect of which is to create conditions of competition which do not correspond to the normal competitive conditions of the market in question, regard being had to the nature of the products or services offered, the size and number of the undertakings, and the volume of the said market. This precludes any direct or indirect contact between competitors, the object or effect of which is to influence conduct on the market of an actual or potential competitor, or to disclose to such competitor the course of conduct which they themselves have decided to adopt or contemplate adopting on the market, thereby facilitating a collusive outcome on the market. Hence, information exchange can constitute a concerted practice if it reduces strategic uncertainty in the market thereby facilitating collusion, that is to say, if the data exchanged is strategic. Consequently, sharing of strategic data between competitors amounts to concentration, because it reduces the independence of competitors’ conduct on the market and diminishes their incentives to compete.
62. A situation where only one undertaking discloses strategic information to its competitor(s) who accept(s) it can also constitute a concerted practice. Such disclosure could occur, for example, through contacts via mail, emails, phone calls, meetings etc. It is then irrelevant whether only one undertaking unilaterally informs its competitors of its intended market behaviour, or whether all participating undertakings inform each other of the respective deliberations and intentions. When one undertaking alone reveals to its competitors strategic information concerning its future commercial policy, that reduces strategic uncertainty as to the future operation of the market for all the competitors involved and
70
increases the risk of limiting competition and of collusive behaviour. For example, mere attendance at a meeting where a company disclose its pricing plans to its competitors is likely to be caught by Article 101, even in the absence of an explicit agreement to raise prices. When a company receives strategic data from a competitor (be it in a meeting, by mail or electronically), it will be presumed to have accepted the information and adapted its market conduct accordingly unless it responds with a clear statement that it does not wish to receive such data.”
(emphasis added)
83) According to us, the real question in the present case is as to
whether there was a possibility of such an agreement having regard to
market conditions even when we proceed on the basis that meeting did
take place. Possibility of such an agreement has been inferred by the CCI
on the grounds that identical bidding takes place thereafter and various
suppliers gave such a bid despite varying cost and also that they have
appoined common changes etc. as pointed out above.
84) The first and foremost issue which needs to be considered is that
whether there was a situation of monopsony or oligopsony.
85) From the aforesaid discussion, it is clear that as far as CCI is
concerned, it has come to the conclusion that there was a cartelisation
among the appellants herein and a concerted decision was taken to rig the
bids which were submitted persuant to the tenders issued by IOCL. On
the other hand, the appellants argue that there was no such agreement
and even if the bids of many bidders were identical in nature, the bids
71
were driven by market conditions. Their plea is that there was a situation
of oligopsony and the modus which was adopted by IOCL in floating the
tenders and awarding the contracts would show that the determination of
price was entirely within the control of the IOCL. As per them, the way
price was determined for supply of these cylinders, it had become an open
secret known to everybody. Therefore, there was no question of any
competition and no possibility of adversely affecting that competition by
entering into any contract.
86) The factors which have influenced the authorities below in coming to
the conclusion that the appellants had colluded and formed a cartel which
led to bid rigging have already been noted above. To recaptulate, the
authorities below have been influenced by the following factors:
1. Market conditions 2. Small number of suppliers 3. Few new entrants 4. Active trade association 5. Repetitive bidding 6. Identical products 7. Few or no substitutes 8. No significant technological changes 9. Meeting of bidders in Mumbai and its agenda. 10. Appointing common agents 11. Identical bids despite varying cost.
After deliberating on the aforesaid aspects, the CCI has concluded
that there is an active trade association in which many of the appellants
72
are members. That product in question, namely, gas cylinder is of a
particular specification which is needed by IOCL in large numbers every
year and there are very few manufacturers and suppliers of this product to
IOCL and two other buyers. For this identical product which is to be
supplied by all the suppliers, there is no substitute and no significant
technology change. Further, there is an active trade association in which
most of the appellants are the members. Their interest is to ensure that
no new entrants are able to join. Further, the trade association also
ensures that all the members are able to get some order. It is for this
reason the bids submitted in various standards which are floated by IOCL
at different places are almost identical despite varying cost. The
authorities below attributed this identical bidding to the concerted action of
the appellants. This has been inferred from the fact that 2-3 days before
the submission of bids, meeting of the association took place which most
of the appellants attended. Not only this, common agents, six in number,
were appointed who submitted the bids on behalf of these appellants.
87) We may say at the outset that if these factors are taken into
consideration by themselves, they may lead to the inference that there
was bid rigging. We may, particularly, emphasise the fact that there is an
active trade association of the appellants and a meeting of the bidders
73
was held in Mumbai just before the submission of the tenders. Another
very important fact is that there were identical bids despite varying cost.
Further, products are identical and there are small number of suppliers
with few new entrants. These have become the supporting factors which
persuaded the CCI to come to the conclusion that these are suggestive of
collusive bidding.
88) However, that is only one side of the coin. The aforesaid factors are
to be analysed keeping in mind the ground realities that were prevailing,
which are pointed out by the appellants. These attendant circumstances
are argued in detail by the counsel for the appellants which have already
been taken note of. We may recapitulate the same in brief hereinbelow:
(i) In the present case there are only three buyers. Among them, IOCL
is the biggest buyer with 48% market share. It is also a matter of record
that all these appellants are manufacturers of 14.2 kg gas cylinders to the
three buyers who are available in the market, nanely, IOCL, HPCL and
BPCL. If these three buyers do not purchase from any of the appellants,
that particular appellant would not be in a position to sell those cylinder to
any other entity as there are no other buyers.
(ii) There are only three buyers, it may not attract many to enter the field
and manufacture these cylinders. It is because of limited number of
74
buyers and for some reason if they do not purchase, the manufacturer
would be nowhere. That may deter the persons to enter the field.
(iii) The manner in which the tenders are floated by IOCL and the rates
at which these are awarded, are an indicator that it is the IOCL which calls
the shots insofar as price control is concerned. It has come in evidence
that the IOCL undertakes the exercise of having its internal estimates
about the cost of these cylinders. Their own expert arrived at a figue of
Rs. 1106.61 paisa per cylinder. All the tenders which have been accepted
are for a price lesser than the aforesaid estimate of IOCL itself. That
apart, the modus adopted by the IOCL is that that final price is negotiated
by it and the contract is not awarded at the rate quoted by bidder who
turns out to be L-1. Negotiations are held with such a bidder who is L-1
which generaly leads to further reduction of price than the one quoted by
L-1. Thereafter, the other bidders who may be L-2 or L-3 etc. are awarded
the contract at the rate at which it is awarded to L-1. Thus, ultimately, all
the bidders supply the goods at the same rate which is fixed by the IOCL
after negotiating with L-1 bidder. The only difference is that bidder who is
L-1 would be able to receive the order for larger quantity than L-2 and L-2
may get an order of more quantity than L-3.
(iv) It has also come on record that there are very few suppliers. For the
75
tender in question, there were 50 parties already in the fray and 12 new
entrants were admitted. Number of 12, in such a scenario, cannot be
treated as less. Therefore, the conclusion of CCI that the appellants
ensured that there should not be entry of new entrant may not be correct.
(v) Since there are not many manufacturers and supplies are needed by
the three buyers on regular basis, IOCL ensures that all those
manufacturers whose bids are technically viable, are given some order for
the supply of specific cylinder. For this purpose, it has framed its broad
policy as well. This also shows that control remains with IOCL.
Thus, the appellants appear to be correct when they say that all the
participants in the bidding process were awarded contracts in some State
or the other which was aimed at ensuring a bigger pool of manufacturers
so that the supply of this essential product is always maintained for the
benefit of the general public. Had IOCL left some manufacturers empty
handed, in all likelihood, they would have shut their shops. However,
IOCL wanted all manufacturers to be in the fray in its own interest.
Therefore, it was necessary to keep all parties afloat and this explains why
all 50 parties obtained order along with 12 new entrants.
(vi) There is another very relevant factor pointed out by the appellants,
viz., the governmental control which is regulated by law. As pointed out
76
above, it is not only the three oil companies which can supply LPG to
domestic consumers in 14.2 kg LPG cylinders as mandated in the LPG
(Regulation and Distribution) Order, 2000 which is issued under the
provisions of Essential Commodities Act, 1955, even the price at which the
LPG cylinder is to be supplied to the consumer is controlled by the
Government. Following features of the aforesaid LPG Order, 2000, are
significant:
• The LPG suppliedin 14.2 kg gas cylinders is an essential commodity.
• The distribution of LPG in 14.2 kgs cylinders takes place as part of a
public distribution system defined under clause 2(1) of the Order as “the
system of distribution, marketing or selling of liquefied petroleum gas by a
Government Oil Company at the Government controlled or declared price
through a distribution system approved by the Central or State
Government”.
• The price to the consumer is controlled by the Government.
• The supply of LPG to domestic consumers shall be made only in 14.2 kg
gas cylinders.
• According to clauses 4 and 5 read with Schedule III of the LPG Order,
parallel marketeers who supply and distribute LPG cylinders, may do so
only for cylinders with size and specifications other than those specified in
77
Schedule II.
89) The manner in which tendering process takes place would show that
in such a competitive scenariao, the bid which the different bidder would
be submitting becomes obvious. It has come on record that just a few
days before the tender in question, another tender was floated by BPCL
and on opening of the said tender the rates of L-1, L-2 etc. came to be
known. In a scenario like this, that obviously becomes a guiding factor for
the bidders to submit their bids.
90) When we keep in mind the aforesaid fact situation on the ground,
those very factors on the basis of which the CCI has come to the
conclusion that there was cartelization, in fact, become valid explanations
to the indicators pointed out by the CCI. We have already commented
about the market conditions and small number of suppliers. We have also
mentioned that 12 new entrants cannot be considered as entry of very few
new suppliers where the existing suppliers were only 50. Identical
products along with market conditions for which there would be only three
buyers, in fact, would go in favour of the appellants. The factor of
repetitive bidding, though appears to be a factor against the appellants,
was also possible in the aforesaid scneario. The prevailing conditions in
fact rule out the possibility of much price variations and all the
78
manufacturers are virtually forced to submit their bid with a price that is
quite close to each other. Therefore, it became necessary to sustain
themselves in the market. Hence, the factor that these suppliers are from
different region having different cost of manufacture would lose its
significance. It is a situation where prime condition is to quote the price at
which a particular manufacturer can bag an order even when its
manufacturing cost is more than the manufacturing cost of others. The
main purpose for such a manufacuring would be to remain in the fray and
not to lose out. Therefore, it would be ready to accept lesser margin. This
would answer why there were near identical bids despite varying cost.
91) Insofar as meeting of bidders in Mumbai just before the date of
submission of tender is concerned, some aspects pointed out by the
appellants are not considered by the CCI or the COMPAT at all. No doubt,
the meeting took place a couple of days before the date of tender. No
doubt, the absence of agenda coming on record would not make much
difference. However, only 19 appellants had attended that meeting. Many
others were not even members or did not attend the meeting. In spite
thereof, even they quoted almost same rates as the one who attended the
meeting. This would lead us to the inference that reason for quoting
similar price was not the meeting but something else. The question is what
79
would be the other reason and whether the appellants have been able to
satisfactorily explain that and rebut the presumption against them?
92) The explanation is market conditions leading to the situation of
oligopsony that prevailed because of limited buyers and influence of
buyers in the fixation of prices was all prevalent. This seems to be
convincing in the given set of facts. The situation of oligopsony can be
both ways. There may be a situation where the sellers are few and they
may control the market and by their concerted action indulge into
cartelization. It may also be, as in the present case, a situation where
buyers are few and that results in the situation of oligopsony with the
control of buyers.
93) To recapitulate, the two prime factors against the appellants, which
are discussed by the CCI, are that there was a collusive tendering, which
is inferred from the parallel behaviour of the appellants, namely, quoting
almost the same rates in their bids. The parameters on the basis of which
these aspects are to be judged are stated in Excel Crop Care Limited as
follows:
80
“50. It needs to be emphasised that collusive tendering is a practice whereby firms agree amongst themselves to collaborate over their response to invitations to tender. Main purpose for such collusive tendering is the need to concert their bargaining power, though, such a collusive tendering has other benefits apart from the fact that it can lead to higher prices. Motive may be that fewer contractors actually bother to price any particular deal so that overheads are kept lower. It may also be for the reason that a contractor can make a tender which it knows will not be accepted (because it has been agreed that another firm will tender at a lower price) and yet it indicates that the said contractor is still interested in doing business, so that it will not be deleted from the tenderee's list. It may also mean that a contractor can retain the business of its established, favoured customers without worrying that they will be poached by its competitors.
51. Collusive tendering takes many forms. Simplest form is to agree to quote identical prices with the hope that all will receive their fair share of orders. That is what has happened in the present case. However, since such a conduct becomes suspicious and would easily attract the attention of the competition authorities, more subtle arrangements of different forms are also made between colluding parties. One system which has been noticed by certain competition authorities in other countries is to notify intended quotes to each other, or more likely to a Central secretariat, which will then cost the order and eliminate those quotes that it considers would result in a loss to some or all members of the cartel. Another system, which has come to light, is to rotate orders. In such a case, the firm whose turn is to receive an order will ensure that its quote is lower than the quotes of others.
52. We are here concerned with parallel behaviour. We are conscious of the argument put forth by Mr Venugopal that in an oligopoly situation parallel behaviour may not, by itself, amount to a concerted practice. It would be apposite to take note of the following observations made by European Court of Justice in Dyestuffs:
“By its very nature, then, the concerted practice does not have all the elements of a contract but may inter alia arise out of coordination which becomes apparent from the behaviour of the participants. Although parallel behaviour may not itself be identified with a concerted practice, it may however amount to strong evidence of such a practice if it leads to conditions of
81
competition which do not respond to the normal conditions of the market, having regard to the nature of the products, the size and number of the undertakings, and the volume of the said market. Such is the case especially where the parallel behaviour is such as to permit the parties to seek price equilibrium at a different level from that which would have resulted from competition, and to crystallise the status quo to the detriment of effective freedom of movement of the products in the [internal] market and free choice by consumers of their suppliers.”
(emphasis supplied)
At the same time, the Court also added that the existence of a concerted practice could be appraised correctly by keeping in mind the following test:
“If the evidence upon which the contested decision is based is considered, not in isolation, but as a whole, account being taken of the specific features of the products in question.”
Having regard to the aforesaid principles in mind, we deal with the
arugment on oligopsony raised by the appellants.
94) Monopsony consists of a market with a single buyer. When there
are only few buyers the market is described as an oligopsony. What is
emphasised is that in such a situation a manufacturer with no buyers will
have to exit from the trade. Therefore, first condition of oligopsony stands
fulfilled. The other condition for the existence of oligopsony is whether the
buyers have some influence over the price of their inputs. It is also to be
seen as to whether the seller has any ability to raise prices or it stood
reduced/eliminated by the aforesaid buyers.
82
95) On a hollistic view of the matter, we find that the appellants have
been able to discharge the onus by referring to various indicators which go
on to show that parallel behaviour was not the result of any concerted
practice.
96) In Dyestuffs, the European Court held that parallel behaviour does
not, by itself, amount to a concerted practice, though it may provide a
strong evidence of such a practice. Nevertheless, it is a strong evidence of
such a practice. However, before such an inference is drawn it has to be
seen that this parallel behaviour has led to conditions of competition which
do not correspond to the normal conditions of the market, having regard to
the nature of the products, size and volume of the undertaking of the said
market. Thus, we examine the matter from the stand point of market
economy where question of oligopsony assumes relevance. Whenever
there is a situation of oligopsony, parallel pricing simplicitor would not lead
to the conclusion that there was a concerted practice there has to be other
credible and corroborative evidence to show that in an oligopoly a
reduction in price would swiftly attract the customers of the other two or
three rivals, the effect upon whom would be so devastating that they would
83
have to react by matching the cut. In Richard Whish & David Bailey in
Oxford’s Competition Law15 discussed the “Theory of Oligopolistic
Interdependence” as under:
“In an oligopoly a reduction in price would swiftly attract the customers of the other two or three rivals, the effect upon whom would be so devastating that they would have to react by matching the cut. Similarly an oligopolist could not increase its price unilaterally, because it would be deserted by its customers if it did so. Thus the theory runs that in an oligopolistic market rivals are interdependent: they are acutely aware of each other’s presence and are bound to match one another’s marketing strategy. The result is that price competition between them will be minimal or non-existent; oligopoly produces non-competitive stability…..
...Oligopolists recognize their interdependence as well as their own self-interest. By matching each other’s conduct they will be able to achieve and charge a profit-maximising price which will be set at a supra-competitive level, without actually communicating with one another. There does not need to be any communication: the structure of the market is such that, through interdependence and mutual self-awareness, prices will rise towards the monopolistic level….
…..The logical conclusion of the case against oligopoly is that, since it is the market structure itself which produces the problem, structural measures should be taken to remedy it by deconcentrating the market. Unless this is done, there will be an area of consciously parallel action in pricing strategies which is beyond the reach of laws against cartels and yet which has serious implications for consumers welfare.
xxx xxx xxx
xxx xxx xxx
(iii) A regulatory approach
15
84
A different possibility would be to regulate the prices of undertakings that operate in an oligopolistic environment. This, however, would be a counsel of despair. As a matter of policy direct regulation should be a remedy of last resort. Competition authorities should not be price regulators; they should be the guardians of the competitive process. Where markets are oligopolistic and entry is limited, competition authorities should be concerned with the question of whether there are barriers to entry and whether the state itself, for example through restrictive licensing rules, regulation or legislation, is responsible for a lack of competition.”
97) In Theatre Enterprises v. Paramount Films16, the Supreme Court
of United States held as under:
“1-3 The crucial question is whether respondents’ conduct toward petitioner stemmed from independent decision or from an agreement, tacit or express. To be sure, business behavior is admissible circumstantial evidence from which the fact finder may infer agreement. Interstate Circuit.
But this Court has never held that proof of parallel business behavior conclusively establishes agreement or, phrased differently, that such behavior itself constitutes a Sherman Act offence. Circumstantial evidence of consciously parallel behavior may have made heavy inroads into the traditional judicial attitude toward conspiracy; but “conscious parallelism” has not yet read conspiracy out of the Sherman Act entirely.”
98) In this regard, the test laid down by the Supreme Court of United
States in Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp.17 is relevant and is
reproduced hereunder:
16 17
85
“The correct standard is that there must be evidence that tends to exclude the possibility that the manufacturer and non-terminated distributors were acting independently. That is, there must be direct or circumstantial evidence that reasonably tends to prove that the manufacturer and others had a conscious commitment to a common scheme designed to achieve an unlawful objective.”
99) This test was reiterated by the Supreme Court of United States in
Matsushita v. Zenith Ratio Corp.18:
“…..But antitrust law limits the range of permissible inferences from ambiguous evidence in a 1 case. Thus, in Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465 U.S. 752 (1984), we held that conduct as consistent with permissible competition as with illegal conspiracy does not, standing alone, support an inference of antitrust conspiracy. Id., at 764. See also Cities Service, supra, at 280. To survive a motion for summary judgment or for a directed verdict, a plaintiff seeking damages for a violation of 1 must present evidence "that tends to exclude the possibility" that the alleged conspirators acted independently. 465 U.S., at 764 …….
…...petitioners had no motive to enter into the alleged conspiracy. To the contrary, as presumably rational businesses, petitioners had every incentive not to engage in the conduct with which they are charged, for its likely effect would be to generate losses for petitioners with no corresponding gains. Cf. Cities Service, 391 U.S., at 279 . The Court of Appeals did not take account of the absence of a plausible motive to enter into the alleged predatory pricing conspiracy. It focused instead on whether there was "direct evidence of concert of action." 723 F.2d, at 304. The Court of Appeals erred in two respects: (i) the "direct evidence" on which the court relied had little, if any, relevance to the alleged predatory pricing conspiracy; and (ii) the court failed to consider the absence of a plausible motive to engage in predatory pricing…..
xxx xxx xxx
Lack of motive bears on the range of permissible conclusions that might be drawn from ambiguous evidence: if petitioners had no rational economic motive to conspire, and if their conduct is
18
86
consistent with other, equally plausible explanations, [475 U.S. 574, 597] the conduct does not give rise to an inference of conspiracy. See Cities Service, supra, at 278-280.”
100) Similarly, in Bell Atlantic Corp v. Twombly19, the U.S. Supreme
Court held as under:
“[1-3] Because §1 of the Sherman Act “does not prohibit [all] unreasonable restraints of trade … but only restraints effected by a contract, combination, or conspiracy,” Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp.,467 U.S. 752,775(1984) , “[t]he crucial question” is whether the challenged anticompetitive conduct “stem[s] from independent decision or from an agreement, tacit or express,” Theatre Enterprises, 346 U. S., at 540. While a showing of parallel “business behavior is admissible circumstantial evidence from which the fact finder may infer agreement,” it falls short of “conclusively establishing agreement or … itself constituting a Sherman Act offense.” Id., at 540–541. Even “conscious parallelism,” a common reaction of “firms in a concentrated market [that] recogniz[e] their shared economic interests and their interdependence with respect to price and output decisions” is “not in itself unlawful.” Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U. S. 209, 227 (1993) ; see 6 P. Areeda & H. Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶1433a, p. 236 (2d ed. 2003) (hereinafter Areeda & Hovenkamp) (“The courts are nearly unanimous in saying that mere interdependent parallelism does not establish the contract, combination, or conspiracy required by Sherman Act §1”); Turner, The Definition of Agreement Under the Sherman Act: Conscious Parallelism and Refusals to Deal, 75Harv. L. Rev. 655, 672 (1962) (“[M]ere interdependence of basic price decisions is not conspiracy”).
[4-6] The inadequacy of showing parallel conduct or interdependence, without more, mirrors the ambiguity of the behavior: consistent with conspiracy, but just as much in line with a wide swath of rational and competitive business strategy unilaterally prompted by common perceptions of the market. See, e.g., AEI-Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies, Epstein, Motions to Dismiss Antitrust Cases: Separating Fact from Fantasy, Related
19
87
Publication 06–08, pp. 3–4 (2006) (discussing problem of “false positives” in §1 suits). Accordingly, we have previously hedged against false inferences from identical behavior at a number of points in the trial sequence. An antitrust conspiracy plaintiff with evidence showing nothing beyond parallel conduct is not entitled to a directed verdict, see Theatre Enterprises, supra; proof of a §1 conspiracy must include evidence tending to exclude the possibility of independent action, see Monsanto Co. v. Spray-Rite Service Corp., 465 U. S. 752 (1984); and at the summary judgment stage a §1 plaintiff’s offer of conspiracy evidence must tend to rule out the possibility that the defendants were acting independently, see Matsushita Elec. Industrial Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574(1986).”
101) After taking note of the test that needs to be applied in such cases,
which was laid down in Dyestuffs and accepted in Excel Crop Care
Limited, we come to the conclusion that the inferences drawn by the CCI
on the basis of evidence collected by it are duly rebutted by the appellants
and the appellants have been able to discharge the onus that shifted upon
them on the basis of factors pointed out by the CCI. However, at that
stage, the CCI failed to carry the matter further by having required and
necessary inquiry that was needed in the instant case.
102) We are emphasising here that in such a watertight tender policy of
IOCL which gave IOCL full control over the tendering process, it was
necessary to summon IOCL. This would have cleared many aspects
which are shrouded in mystery and the dust has not been cleared.
88
103) We, thus, arrive at a conclusion that there is no sufficient evidence to
hold that there was any agreement between the appellants for bid rigging.
Accordingly, we allow these appeals and set aside the order of the
Authorities below. As a consequence, since no penalty is payable, appeals
of the CCI are rendered infructuous and dismissed as such. All the
pending applications stand disposed of.
No orders as to costs.
.............................................J. (A.K. SIKRI)
.............................................J. (ASHOK BHUSHAN)
NEW DELHI; OCTOBER 01, 2018.